Dinu C. Giurescu: Ce-am avut si ce-am distrus

Radiografia acad. Dinu C Giurescu asupra societatii romanesti

  • Baza industrială existentă în 1989 a dispărut. Numeric, cel puţin 80% din capacităţile de producţie au fost date la fier vechi. În Bucureşti existau în decembrie 1989 cel puţin 47 mari întreprinderi. Au dispărut complet 34
  • Tot efortul de industrializare al României din secolul XX a fost în cea mai mare parte anulat. O atare distrugere a industriei proprii este, după toate probabilităţile, unică în Europa dacă nu şi în lume. România nu mai are în proprietate nici o unitate industrială, cele în funcţie aparţin firmelor straine
  • Cooperaţia meşteşugărească de producţie a dispărut şi ea în cea mai mare parte. Dacă vrei să-ţi repari un pantof, găsirea unui atelier seamănă cu un joc la loterie.
  • Agricultura, prin măsurile luate în anii ’90, a revenit la o fărâmiţare care o fac neproductivă. România nu mai produce hrana de care are nevoie şi importă nu numai grâu, dar şi legume, fructe din ţări europene, africane şi chiar din America de Sud
  • Comerţul se desfăşoară în mall-uri cu megamagazine. Care este ponderea în megamagazine a mărfurilor produse în România? Imaginile cu înghesuiala cumpărătorilor de sărbători la casele de marcat nu înseamnă bunăstare
  • Comerţul exercitat individual-particular s-a redus la maximum; micile magazine de cartier unele rezistă, altele s-au închis, iar ponderea lor este prea puţin semnificativă.
  • Sistemul bancar-financiar aparţine, în proporţie de cel puţin 90% – băncilor străine
  • De ce până în 2009 inclusiv, au fost bani şi dintr-odată nu mai sunt? Opinia publică nu a primit o explicaţie raţională şi nici cum sunt folosite aceste 20 de miliarde
  • Urmările împrumutului: a) reducerea cu 25% a salariilor şi cu 15% a pensiilor

b) disponibilizări repetate în 2010, 2011 si 2012 c) reducerea în continuare a salariilor întrucât noua grilă de salarizare a pornit de la un prag mai jos decât acela anterior d) îngheţarea salariilor şi pensiilor pe 2012 e) hotărâri judecătoreşti definitive pentru plata unor drepturi băneşti nu sunt respectate şi amânate cu motivarea că nu sunt bani f) investitiile sunt îndreptate spre firmele clientelare ale regimului

  • FMI execută un control direct asupra bugetului şi administraţiei ţării. Acest for „recomandă“ ce trebuie privatizat sau pus sub management privat. Într-un fel, situaţia se aseamănă cu aceea a României din anii 1948-1958 când hotărârile conducerii de atunci erau supuse aprobării prealabile a Moscovei
  • Trecerea – tot la recomandarea FMI – sub management privat a unor mari unităţi care mai sunt proprietatea statului
  • Vânzarea în continuare a resurselor naturale, exploatarea perimetrelor maritime petrolifere; atacarea pădurilor virgine.Veniturile ce vor reveni statului român din vânzarea unor asemenea resurse sunt minimale

Conducerea politica,degradare fara precedent

  • Viaţa politică cunoaşte, în ultimii 6-7 ani, manifestări aparte, care încalcă atât Constituţia ţării, cât şi regulile UE
  • Formarea unei majorităţi parlamentare cu ajutorul unui „partid“ care nu a fost validat în alegeri şi votează automat cu partidul principal de guvernământ
  • Metode speciale de votare : asumarea răspunderii de către guvern; aprobarea tacită ; numărătoare în viteză (numărătoarea expres) ; ordonanţele de urgenţă aprobate în bloc
  • Politizarea aparatului de stat până la treptele inferioare. Se va ajunge la partidul-stat existent în 1989
  • Transformarea guvernului într-un simplu instrument de execuţie, de aplicare a dispoziţiilor Preşedinţiei
  • Eliminarea completă a dialogului dintre partide pentru obţinerea unei soluţii negociate; compromisul politic nu există în mentalul şi practica partidului principal de guvernământ; există numai dorinţa de eliminare cu orice preţ şi prin orice mijloace a adversarilor
  • Jaloane pentru fraudarea viitoarelor alegeri : votarea prin corespondenţă, tinerea concomitentă a viitoarelor alegeri, locale şi parlamentare, contrar prevederilor constituţionale, cât şi a practicii UE
  • Prin mai multe iniţiative legislative sau de facto din ultimii ani, guvernul se îndreaptă spre destrămarea teritorială şi juridică a statului român.
  • Atacarea teritoriului. Împărţirea Transilvaniei în două regiuni de dezvoltare pe linia despărţitoare trasată de dictatul de la Viena din august 1940. O atare propunere care deschide calea unei divizări de facto – economice şi etnice – a Transilvaniei. Ce mai rămâne din definiţia România stat naţional unitar şi indivizibil?
  • Integritatea teritorială este pusă direct sub semnul întrebării şi prin: proiectul de desfiinţare a judeţelor existente
  • Politica oficială (guvernamentală) faţă de comunele româneşti din judeţul Covasna este şi ea grăitoare: aceste localităţi – prin reprezentanţii lor – nu au primit nici un fel de sprijin bănesc de la guvern pentru activităţile lor culturale.
  • Alcătuirea statală este pusă la îndoială prin criticarea şi blamarea repetată a diferitelor categorii socio-profesionale: medici, judecători, profesori, poliţişti; prin referiri negative privind instituţii ale statului.
  • Legea arhivelor acum în faza de promulgare reprezintă încă o lovitură dată statului român. Legea îngăduie scoaterea unor arhive originale şi restituirea lor către emitenţi. Aplicarea unei asemenea legi înseamnă aprobarea legală pentru destrămarea arhivelor naţionale cu toate consecinţele previzibile
  • Reforma sănătăţii a dus la închiderea a zeci de unităţi, tot în numele economiilor bugetare. Faza a doua a acestei reforme preconizează acum limitarea asistenţei medicale la un pachet-tip
  • Codul muncii votat nu demult este net în defavoarea salariaţilor şi acordă angajatorilor mai multe înlesniri în desfacerea contractelor de muncă
  • Prin desfiinţarea industriei existente în 1989 în proporţie de cel puţin 80%, prin închiderea atelierelor meşteşugăreşti şi prin emigrarea a peste 2.000.000 de persoane,muncitorimea din România s-a redus considerabil şi numeric dar şi ca forţă de acţiune
  • Siguranţa personală a cetăţeanului şi a bunurilor sale este ameninţată de limitarile bugetare si concedierile masive in Politie si Jandarmerie
  • Îngheţarea salariilor şi a pensiilor pe de o parte şi creşterea preţurilor pe de altă parte, îngrădesc şi chiar opresc reacţiile corpului social preocupat zilnic de cum să facă faţă cheltuielilor de supravieţuire.
  • Măsurile luate sub lozinca „reformei instituţionale“ erodează pas cu pas statul român, slăbesc autoritatea instituţiilor sale. Cetăţeanul se simte astăzi mai expus presiunilor de tot felul şi mai nesigur de viitorul său şi al copiilor săi decât cu 6-7 ani în urmă
  • Atitudinea indiferentă a oficialităţilor faţă de tot ce aminteşte identitatea românească, tradiţiile, personalităţile reprezentative, istoria, limba vorbită astăzi tot mai stâlcită
  • Noua lege a educatiei favorizeaza formarea unei generatii fara identitate nationala

Dinu C. Giurescu, Decembrie 2011

Criza europeana si sansa Romaniei – o viziune neoconservatoare

Criza europeana si sansa Romaniei – o viziune neoconservatoare

Razvan Timofciuc:  „Europa liberală, la care părinţii fondatori visau, se transformă în Europa imperială, la care visau Hitler şi Joachim von Ribbentrop”.

„Europa Unita” este o utopie. Europa a fost din punct de vedere cultural si religios intotdeauna divizata.  Incepand din 1054 Europa sa impartit in doua entitati, spatiul catolic-prostestant si spatiul bizantin. Ambele entitati cultural-religioase sau dezvoltat separat. Decalajele de dezvoltare, mentalitatiile diferite sunt vizibile, iar criza capitalismului neokeyniasan va duce la renationalizarea Uniunii Europene.

Motorul renationalizarii este produsul Sfantei Aliante Merkoziene. Cine vorbeste astazi de „Europa Unita”, vorbeste de fapt de interesele franco-germane camunflate in drapelul european.

Cine profita de „Europa Unita”? Holdingurile de stat franceze si capitalul german.

Renationalizarea europeana nu se va termina aici. Implozia monedei euro va duce la nasterea unor noi sfere economice si politice. Franta nu va renunta niciodata la Francul Francez (moneda care astazi se numeste Euro), iar Germania va reintroduce Noua Marca Germana si va forma alaturi de alte state europene, zona economica cu acelasi nume.

Schimbariile din spatiul cultural catolic-protestant vor afecta intregul continent.

Spatiul bizantin nu a avut niciodata ritmul de progres impus de Renastere si Iluminism. Elitele bizantine au preferat pasalicul otoman, cultura peschesului, baksishului, economia de taraba, si alte schmeckerii si improvizatii fanariote.

Capitalismul, monarhia parlamentara, republica prezidentiala si curentele politice moderne au fost rezultatul unor procese si revolutii politice dezvoltate si amplificate politic in Occidentul catolic-protestant.

Spatiul neobizantin nu a avut o asemenea evolutie. Cand la Paris se discuta in saloane luminate principiile doctrinare ale constitutionalismului, pe dealurile si campiile balcanice ciobanasul neobizantin fluiera liber-cugetator o doina.

Spatiul neobizantin sa afirmat ca entitate sociala in perioada decaderii Imperiului Otoman, Reformele institutionale au fost aplicate in urma unor matritze copiate ale unor modele occidentale. Sa nu uitam ca intreg spatiul bizantin a fost rezultatul unor razboaie regionale si ale unor conferinte de pace sustinute si parafate in Occident: Paris (1856), Berlin (1878), Versailles (1919), Trianon (1920).

Cand elitele neobizantine iluminate in Occident au apus, au aparut elite national-religioase care au impus modele politice autoritare. Bizantul urma sa fie ocupat mai intii de Germania nazista si ulterior a apartinut hegemonului sovietic. Din nou Bizantul a fost impartit si adjudecat in urma unor tratate si conventii internationale:  Pactul Ribentropp-Molotow (1939), Conferinta de la Teheran (1943), Planul Morgenthau (1944). Prin Tratatele de la Jalta si Potsdam (1945) soarta Bizantului a fost pecetluita pentru cinci decenii.

Dupa 1989 Bizantul sa adaptat cu greu la normele culturale si institutional-politice catolic-protestante. Euforia „Europei Unite” a sfarsit in genocidul de la Srebenitza. Astazi Bizantul a ajuns o anexa costisitoare si complicata a Uniunii Europene.

Tarile balcanice catolice si protestante Slovenia si Croatia apartin UE. Bosnia si Kosovo sunt protectorate UE. Serbia, Macedonia, Albania, Republica Moldova sunt tinute in anti-camera UE. Romania si Bulgaria, tari profund bizantine, sunt stigmatizate si tinute departe de catre pozitiile cheie ale institutelor europene.

Grecia, tara-mama al Bizantului, este supusa unui regim de guvernare care se aseamana unui directorat. Ceea ce vedem in acest moment este pe departe „Europa Unita”, ci un puzzle neterminat, un caleisdoscop ale contrastelor europene.

Cum va arata viitorul Uniunii Europene? Sansa Europei este sa ramina unita, dar totodata diversificata.

Cu siguranta un spatiu juridic comun ale tariilor membre UE este un proiect consensual.

Pe plan economic Uniunea Europeana se va diviza in patru sectoare: 1). flancul tarilor PIIGS, 2). zona economica Noua Marca Germana formata din Germania, Austria, Finlanda, Olanda, Luxemburg, 3). restul zonei Euro si 4) tariile membre UE care isi vor pastra moneda nationala.

In paralel cu sedimentarea si separarea economica, institutiile politice se vor reseta conform noi geometrii europene.

Secesiunea economica este insa si o sansa pentru Romania. Tara noastra, de jure integrata in UE, de facto neintegrata si tinuta departe de institutiile cheie, se poate afirma din punct de vedere economic alaturi de tari mediane precum Slovacia, Polonia si Suedia.

Politic, Romania este nevoita sa iasa din menghina institutionala franco-germana si sa se alature plutonului britanic. Marea Britanie poseda cel mai liberal sistem politic din Europa: monarhia parlamentara.

Inca din 1688 parlamentul britanic sa emancipat in fata regelui si conflictul institutional parlament-rege sa soldat cu detronarea regelui autoritar. In nicio tara europeana, separarea puterilor in stat nu este mai vizibila decat in sistemul parlamentar britanic. In Franta si Germania centrul de putere sa mutat in administratia prezidentiala, respectiv in cancelaria federala.

Criza europeana este insusi o sansa de dezvoltare si modernizare a Romaniei conform propriilor parametri culturali si politici. Probleme societatii romane pot fi solutionate numai de catre elitele romane. Suveranitatea nationala poate fi conservata numai alaturi de tari care doresc sa isi pastreze suveranitatea: Slovacia, Suedia, Polonia si Marea Britanie.

Stratfor.com: „Europe’s Crisis: Beyond Finance”

Autor: George Friedman

Sursa informationala: Stratfor.com

Everyone is wondering about the next disaster to befall Europe. Italy is one focus; Spain is also a possibility. But these crises are already under way. Instead, the next crisis will be political, not in the sense of what conventional politician is going to become prime minister, but in the deeper sense of whether Europe’s political elite can retain power, or whether new political forces are going to emerge that will completely reshape the European political landscape. If this happens, it will be by far the most important consequence of the European financial crisis.

Thus far we have seen some changes in personalities in the countries at the center of the crisis. In Greece, Prime Minister George Papandreou stepped aside, while in Italy Prime Minister Silvio Berlusconi now has resigned. Though these resignations have represented a formal change of government, they have not represented a formal policy change. In fact, Papandreou and Berlusconi both stepped down on the condition that their respective governments adopt the austerity policies proposed during their respective tenures.

Europeanists dominate the coalitions that have replaced them. They come from the generation and class that are deeply intellectually and emotionally committed to the idea of Europe. For them, the European Union is not merely a useful tool for achieving national goals. Rather, it is an alternative to nationalism and the horrors that nationalism has brought to Europe. It is a vision of a single Continent drawn together in a common enterprise — prosperity — that abolishes the dangers of a European war, creates a cooperative economic project and, least discussed but not trivial, returns Europe to its rightful place at the heart of the international political system.

For the generation of leadership born just after World War II that came to political maturity in the last 20 years, the European project was an ideological given and an institutional reality. These leaders formed an international web of European leaders who for the most part all shared this vision. This leadership extended beyond the political sphere: Most European elites were committed to Europe (there were, of course, exceptions).

Greece and the Struggle of the European Elite

Now we are seeing this elite struggle to preserve its vision. When Papandreou called for a referendum on austerity, the European elite put tremendous pressure on him to abandon his initiative. Given the importance of the austerity agreements to the future of Greece, the idea of a referendum made perfect sense. A referendum would allow the Greek government to claim its actions enjoyed the support of the majority of the Greek people. Obviously, it is not clear that the Greeks would have approved the agreement.

Led by German Chancellor Angela Merkel, the European elite did everything possible to prevent such an outcome. This included blocking the next tranche of bailout money and suspending all further bailout money until Greek politicians could commit to all previously negotiated austerity measures. European outrage at the idea of a Greek referendum makes perfect sense.

Coming under pressure from Greece and the European elite, Papandreou resigned and was replaced by a former vice president of the European Central Bank. Already abandoned by Papandreou, the idea of a referendum disappeared.

Two dimensions explain this outcome. The first was national. The common perception in the financial press is that Greece irresponsibly borrowed money to support extravagant social programs and then could not pay off the loans. But there also is validity to the Greek point of view. From this perspective, under financial pressure, the European Union was revealed as a mechanism for Germany to surge exports into developing EU countries via the union’s free trade system. Germany also used Brussels’ regulations and managed the euro such that Greece found itself in an impossible situation. Germany then called on Athens to impose austerity on the Greek people to save irresponsible financiers who, knowing perfectly well what Greece’s economic position was, were eager to lend money to the Greeks. Each version of events has some truth to it, but the debate ultimately was between the European and Greek elites. It was an internal dispute, and whether for Greece’s benefit or for the European financial system’s benefit, both sides were committed to finding a solution.

The second dimension had to do with the Greek public and the Greek and European elites. The Greek elite clearly benefited financially from the European Union. The Greek public, by contrast, had a mixed experience. Certainly, the 20 years of prosperity since the 1990s benefited many — but not all. Economic integration left the Greek economy wide open for other Europeans to enter, putting segments of the Greek economy at a terrific disadvantage. European competitors overwhelmed workers in many industries along with small-business owners in particular. So there always was an argument in Greece for opposing the European Union. The stark choice posed by the current situation strengthened this argument, namely, who would bear the burden of the European system’s dysfunction in Greece? In other words, assuming the European Union was to be saved, who would absorb the cost? The bailouts promised by Germany on behalf of Europe would allow the Greeks to stabilize their financial system and repay at least some of their loans to Europe. This would leave the Greek elite generally intact. The price to Greece would be austerity, but the Greek elite would not pay that price. Members of the broader public — who would lose jobs, pensions, salaries and careers — would.

Essentially, the first question was whether Greece as a nation would deliberately default on its debts — as many corporations do — and force a restructuring on its terms regardless of what the European financial system needed, or whether it would seek to accommodate the European system. The second was whether it would structure an accommodation in Europe such that the burden would not fall on the public but on the Greek elite.

The Greek government chose to seek accommodation with European needs and to allow the major impact of austerity to fall on the public as a consequence of the elite’s interests in Europe — now deep and abiding — and the ideology of Europeanism. Since by its very nature the burden of austerity would fall on the public, it was vital a referendum not be held. Even so, the Greeks undoubtedly would seek to evade the harshest dimensions of austerity. That is the social contract in Greece: The Greeks would promise the Europeans what they wanted, but they would protect the public via duplicity. While that approach might work in Greece, it cannot work in a country like Italy, whose exposure is too large to hide via duplicity. Similarly, duplicity cannot be the ultimate solution to the European crisis.

The Real European Crisis

And here we come to the real European crisis. Given the nature of the crisis, which we have seen play out in Greece, the European elite can save the European concept and their own interests only by transferring the cost to the broader public, and not simply among debtors. Creditors like Germany, too, must absorb the cost and distribute it to the public. German banks simply cannot manage to absorb the losses. Like the French, they will have to be recapitalized, meaning the cost will fall to the public.

Europe was not supposed to work this way. Like Immanuel Kant’s notion of a “Perpetual Peace,” the European Union promised eternal prosperity. That plus preventing war were Europe’s great promises; there was no moral project beyond these. Failure to deliver on either promise undermines the European project’s legitimacy. If the price of retaining Europe is a massive decline in Europeans’ standard of living, then the argument for retaining the European Union is weakened.

As important, if Europe is perceived as failing because the European elite failed, and the European elite is perceived as defending the European idea as a means of preserving its own interests and position, then the public’s commitment to the European idea — never as robust as the elite’s commitment — is put in doubt. The belief in Europe that the crisis can be managed within current EU structures has been widespread. The Germans, however, have floated a proposal that would give creditors in Europe — i.e., the Germans — the power to oversee debtors’ economic decisions. This would undermine sovereignty dramatically. Losing sovereignty for greater prosperity would work in Europe. Losing it to pay back the debts of Europe’s banks is a much harder sell.

The Immigrant Factor and Upcoming Elections

All of this comes at a time of anti-immigrant, particularly anti-Muslim, feeling among the European public. In some countries, anger increasingly has been directed at the European Union and its borders policies — and at European countries’ respective national and international elites, who have used immigration to fuel the economy while creating both economic and cultural tensions in the native population. Thus, immigration has become linked to general perceptions of the European Union, opening both a fundamental economic and cultural divide between European elites and the public.

Racial and ethnic tensions combined with economic austerity and a sense of betrayal toward the elite creates an explosive mixture. Europe experienced this during the inter-war period, though this is not a purely European phenomenon. Disappointment in one’s personal life combined with a feeling of cultural disenfranchisement by outsiders and the sense that the elite is neither honest, nor competent nor committed to the well-being of its own public tends to generate major political reactions anywhere in the world.

Europe has avoided an explosion thus far. But the warning signs are there. Anti-European and anti-immigrant factions existed even during the period when the European Union was functioning, with far-right parties polling up to 16 percent in France. It is not clear that the current crisis has strengthened these elements, but how much this crisis will cost the European public and the absence of miraculous solutions also have not yet become clear. As Italy confronts its crisis, the cost — and the inevitably of the cost — will become clearer.

A large number of elections are scheduled or expected in Europe in 2012 and 2013, including a French presidential election in 2012 and German parliamentary elections in 2013. At the moment, these appear set to be contests between the conventional parties that have dominated Europe since World War II in the West and since 1989 in the East. In general, these are the parties of the elite, all more or less buying into Europe. But anti-European factions have emerged within some of these parties, and as sentiment builds, new parties may form and anti-European factions within existing parties may grow. A crisis of this magnitude cannot happen without Tea Party- and Occupy Wall Street-type factions emerging. In Europe, however — where in addition to economics the crisis is about race, sovereignty, national self-determination and the moral foundations of the European Union — these elements will be broader and more intense.

Populist sentiment coupled with racial and cultural concerns is the classic foundation for right-wing nationalist parties. The European left in general is part of the pro-European elite. Apart from small fragments, very little of the left hasn’t bought into Europe. It is the right that has earned a meaningful following by warning about Europe over the past 20 years. It thus would seem reasonable to expect that these factions will become much stronger as the price of the crisis — and who is going to bear it — becomes apparent.

The real question, therefore, is not how the financial crisis works out. It is whether the European project will survive. And that depends on whether the European elite can retain its legitimacy. That legitimacy is not gone by any means, but it is in the process of being tested like never before, and it is difficult to see how the elite retains it. The polls don’t show the trend yet because the magnitude of the impact on individual lives has not manifested itself in most of Europe. When it does show itself, there will be a massive recalculation regarding the worth and standing of the European elite. There will be calls for revenge, and vows of never allowing such a thing to recur.

Regardless of whether the next immediate European crisis is focused on Spain or Italy, it follows that by mid-decade, Europe’s political landscape will have shifted dramatically, with new parties, personalities and values emerging. The United States shares much of this trend, but its institutions are not newly invented. Old and not working creates problems; new and not working is dangerous. Why the United States will take a different path is a subject for another time. Suffice it to say that the magnitude of Europe’s problems goes well beyond finance.

The European crisis is one of sovereignty, cultural identity and the legitimacy of the elite. The financial crisis has several outcomes, all bad. Regardless of which is chosen, the impact on the political system will be dramatic.

Dinu Zamfirescu, despre prima manifestatie anticomunista din 8 noiembrie 1945

Lectia istoriei:

Mitingul din 8 noiembrie 1945, organizat cu prilejul aniversării onomasticii Maiestăţii Sale Regele Mihai I. Deşi guvernul lui Petru Groza, instalat violent la 6 martie 1945, continua să funcţioneze, artificial, alimentat din fotoliile „roşii“ de la Moscova, românii încă nu voiau să se predea utopiei bolşevice.
Încă nu era clar, dar România liberă se pregătea să intre într-o lungă hibernare, iar democraţia devenea o simplă umbrelă pentru deciziile luate la Kremlin. Un singur exemplu: era prima dată când un premier refuza să demisioneze atunci când Regele i-o cerea. Încă nu puteau accepta românii că ţara lor e condamnată să fie transformată într-o anexă sovietică, dar comuniştii retuşau orice fisură apărea în regimul care avea să devină atât de ermetic.
Cu entuziasmul şi fermitatea unor viitori politicieni, studenţii liberali şi ţărănişti au organizat, la 8 noiembrie 1945, în faţa Palatului Regal din Capitală, prima manifestaţie promonarhică, deci antiguvernamentală, de amploare – începutul rezistenţei anticomuniste a poporului român. Un episod însângerat al confruntărilor dintre comunişti şi „Opoziţia” fidelă Regelui Mihai I. 25.000 de oameni, majoritatea bucureşteni, au participat la miting: şi studenţi, şi pensionari, şi muncitori, şi intelectuali, toţi – conduşi de aceeaşi credinţă că nu-şi vor vinde ţara. Concomitent, în municipii precum Cluj, Sibiu, Braşov, Ploieşti, Giurgiu, Galaţi, Iaşi, Constanţa şi Timişoara au fost organizate acţiuni similare. În Capitală însă, manifestaţia a fost înăbuşită brutal, în stilul tradiţional comunist, cu bâte, gloanţe şi alte astfel de metode „minereşti”, cunoscute în detaliu şi de românii anilor ’90.

Dosarul „Afacerea 8 noiembrie” din arhivele Siguranţei conţine un rezumat de 68 de pagini şi mii de file scrise de securiştii zeloşi despre cei mai vocali participanţi şi despre cei reţinuţi. Printre arestaţi se numără liberalul Radu Câmpeanu, pe atunci, preşedintele Tineretului Universitar Liberal şi unul dintre organizatorii mitingului, şi liberalul Dinu Zamfirescu, elev la Liceul „Spiru Haret” în acea perioadă.

Guvernul decisese, la 24 octombrie, că ziua de naştere a Regelui Mihai (n.r. – 25 octombrie) poate fi sărbătorită abia la 8 noiembrie, odată cu onomastica sa, pentru a comprima cele două festivităţi în numele monarhiei. Mai mult, pentru a înăbuşi din faşă orice fel de manifestare, în noaptea de 24/25 octombrie au fost arestaţi mai mulţi ţărănişti şi liberali din Capitală. Reprezentanţii partidelor istorice nutreau însă alt plan: trebuia, cu orice preţ, să arate Occidentului că românii vor să fie liberi! Se ştia că soarta României este rânduită la Moscova, deci era vital să fie transmis un mesaj puternic… În plus, preşedintele american Harry Truman îl trimisese, în România şi Bulgaria, pe ziaristul Mark Ethridge, pentru a-l informa în legătură cu situaţia politică şi economică din cele două state. Prilejul perfect – Ziua Regelui.

Astfel, ideea mitingului promonarhic a venit firesc, în şedinţa Biroului Politic al PNŢ din 25 octombrie. „Nu este demn de un partid ca PNŢ să folosească prilejul onomasticii Regelui, adică să se ascundă sub hlamida regală pentru a ţine o întrunire. Să nu convocăm nicio întrunire, ci să lăsăm pe prietenii noştri şi să-i îndemnăm ca, dacă se face o demonstraţie cetăţenească pentru MS Regele Mihai, să participe şi membrii partidului”, spunea Ion Mihalache. „Manifestaţia să rămână exclusiv populară şi naţională”, îl completa şi Iuliu Maniu. Liderii ţărănişti au decis astfel, alături de preşedintele liberalilor, Constantin (Dinu) I.C. Brătianu, ca cele două partide să lase populaţia să manifeste pentru Rege, dar să-i susţină, ca simpli cetăţeni. Degeaba tuna şi fulgera ministrul de Externe Ana Pauker că „unii de peste mări şi ţări s-au obişnuit ca numai alde Maniu şi Brătianu să conducă ţara noastră, or orice învăţ are şi dezvăţ”.

„Jos Groza bumbăcit!”

Tineretul celor două partide a început astfel să pregătească ceea ce urma să devină cea mai mare demonstraţie promonarhică din România aproape comunistă. Chiar din primele zile ale lunii noiembrie, au început să tipărească şi să răspândească manifeste, chemându-i pe bucureşteni să-şi declare dragostea pentru Rege şi democraţie.

„Români! Veniţi în ziua de 8 noiembrie, orele 10.00 a.m. pentru a vă manifesta dragostea pentru suveran! Trăiască M.S. Regele!”, scria pe unele manifeste. „Vă cheamă Maniu. Vă cheamă Brătianu. Vă cheamă conştinţa românească. Trăiască Regele! Jos Groza bumbăcit!”, proclamau altele.

Singurul ziar care a avut îndrăzneala de a susţine manifestaţia a fost „Ardealul”, publicaţie de orientare naţional-ţărănistă. În ciuda presiunilor, directorul Anton Mureşanu a publicat pe prima pagina a ziarului din 7 noiembrie acest anunţ: „Toată suflarea românească va fi prezentă în ziua de 8 noiembrie a.c., orele 10 – 1, înainte de masă, în Piaţa Palatului, pentru a-şi manifesta dragostea, devotamentul şi neclintita încredere faţă de iubitul nostru Rege Mihai I. Nu vom lipsi la această mare sărbătoare a poporului românesc. Ţara şi Regele sunt singurele realităţi ale existenţei şi afirmării neamului Românesc!” Mai mult, în seara anterioară, bucureştenii erau sunaţi la telefon şi o voce necunoscută le spunea: „Dacă eşti român, mâine la 10 să fii în Piaţa Palatului”.

„Vreţi şi viaţa noastră?”

„Nu v-aţi îmbogăţit îndeajus, domnilor comunişti, ce mai voiţi de la noi? Cu un an în urmă, casa partidului vostru nu avea ca fond de propagandă nici o sută de lei, iar astăzi are sute de milioane, nu vă este destul? Vreţi şi viaţa noastră?”, scria, în jurnalul său, Constantin Rădulescu Motru, la o zi după manifestaţia din 8 noiembrie. „Toate declaraţiile lui Molotov (n.r. – ministrul rus de Externe) că va respecta suveranitatea statului român au fost simple viclenii”, continua marele academician la 13 noiembrie.

„Era un entuziasm extraordinar. E foarte greu pentru cei de astăzi să înţeleagă. Numai determinarea aceasta a permis să treci peste riscurile evidente. Dar ne sărutau cucoanele!”

Radu Câmpeanu
participant la miting

Începutul măreţ al manifestaţiei de la 8 noiembrie a fost consemnat şi în rapoartele poliţiei – atât de impunător a fost încât nici măcar cenzura nu a găsit o variantă de compromis. Începând cu ora 9.00, în Piaţa Palatului Regal îşi făcea apariţia un grup de peste 30 de invalizi de război, împingând cărucioarele către statuia Regelui Carol I, amplasată chiar în faţa palatului. Veneau de la Căminul invalizilor şi agitau drapele, ovaţionându-o pe Maiestatea Sa! În câteva minute, grupurile de elevi şi studenţi care erau răspândite în jur au alergat către seniori. „Trăiască Regele!” şi „Regele şi Patria!”, strigau toţi, iar manifestanţii începeau să nu se mai teamă de nimic.

Această mărturie din raportul unui agent de securitate, rămasă în Arhivele Prefecturii Poliţiei Capitalei, este emblematică: „A apărut un invalid care în fugă s-a aruncat pe treptele statuii, în mijlocul grupului de invalizi, înconjuraţi de manifestanţi, şi a desfăşurat un steag tricolor mare, în uralele publicului care manifesta pentru Rege”.

Liberalul Radu Câmpeanu, unul dintre organizatorii mitingului, care avea pe atunci doar 23 ani, recompune atmosfera studenţească plină de entuziasm de la primele ore ale dimineţii şi descrie solidaritatea bucureştenilor, care s-au raliat necondiţionat manifestanţilor. „Am hotărât să ne adunăm mai întâi la sediul partidului de pe strada Maria Rosetti, alături de alţi tineri care voiau să ni se alăture. Au venit în jur de 1.000 de persoane străine la sediu, iar studenţii liberali erau grupaţi în parcul din spate, într-o grădină mare”.

Radu Câmpeanu le-a vorbit celor prezenţi şi, înflăcăraţi de discursul pasional, dar şi de ordinul lui Teohari Georgescu de a interzice manifestaţia, studenţii au plecat către Palatul Regal. „Ne-am organizat pe o coloană, cu 15 oameni pe rând. Ne mai bătuserăm cu comuniştii de mai multe ori, aşa că ştiam să ne protejăm – luasem nişte steaguri, cu o bară mică de lemn. Ne-am luat de braţe cu toţii şi, ţinându-ne strâns, am plecat spre bulevard”, îşi aminteşte liberalul.

„Erau cucoane care se dădeau jos din tramvaie, coborau din blocuri, voiau să ne sărute, să ne îmbrăţişeze, Doamne!, ce entuziasm! Ne sărutau cucoanele! Când am ajuns în faţa Societăţii de telefoane, toate funcţionarele au coborât, aşa îmbrăcate în bluzele lor verzui. Toate au venit, domnule, toate! Ca să-ţi dai seama cât de mare se făcuse coloana, îţi mărturisesc că, în timp ce prima linie era la Cercul Militar, ultima ajungea la Cinematograful Scala!”, rememorează Radu Câmpeanu. Peste 10.000 de persoane au ajuns, cu grupul de liberali, în Piaţa Palatului. Chiar şi Garda Palatului s-a s-a alăturat manifestanţilor!

N-a durat mult entuziasmul tinerilor, liberali, ţărănişti sau, pur şi simplu, monarhişti, deci anticomunişti. Forţele de ordine au început arestările, iar de la distanţă (din sediul Ministerului de Interne) chiar se trăgea! Erau acolo detaşamente armate din divizia „Tudor Vladimirescu”. Radu Câmpeanu a ajuns şi el într-o celulă de la subsolul „Internelor”.

Liberalul Dinu Zamfirescu era, în vremea aceea, elev la Liceul „Spiru Haret”, din Capitală – coleg de clasă cu fostul preşedinte Ion Iliescu. Despre momentele tensionate ale mitingului îşi aminteşte perfect! „Am hotărât că nu vom merge la şcoală, deşi 8 noiembrie fusese declarată zi lucrătoare. La 7 dimineaţa, eu am fost însă la liceu, dar cu un lanţ şi cu un lacăt, pentru a lega poarta. Să nu intre nimeni!”, povesteşte liberalul de mai târziu. Deşi, pe atunci, nu era membru de partid, deşi era apropiat liberalilor, elevul Dinu din a XI-a s-a alăturat unui grup restrâns de ţărănişti pentru a ajunge în Piaţa Palatului. Studenţii PNŢ se organizau în echipe reduse, în diferite zone ale Capitalei, urmând să se unească abia în faţa Palatului Regal.

„Chiar când am intrat pe strada Ştirbei Vodă, să merg la întâlnire, m-a abordat un bărbat pe ruseşte: «Cât este ceasul?» I-am tras o înjurătură şi l-am întrebat: «Ai uitat să vorbeşti româneşte?». După ce am ajuns la statuia lui Carol I, am început să strigăm, cu cei prezenţi acolo, «Regele şi Patria», «Libertate şi dreptate», sau chiar «Anglia şi America». Nu erau lozinci ostile, şi nici noi nu eram. Manifestam paşnic.” La ora 10.00 însă au apărut primele forţe de represiune, camuflate în muncitori fideli guvernării: un şir de camioane au apărut dinspre Athenée Palace, purtând insigna CGM – Confederaţia Generală a Muncii, sindicat condus de Gheorghe Apostol.

„Au început să coboare oameni din camioanele astea şi, când noi strigam «Regele şi Patria», ei strigau «Groza şi poporul», iar când strigam noi «Regele», ei făceau semn la gât, că ne taie capul. Camioanele astea au început să dea ocol statuii, în formaţie, şi să ne strângă cât mai mult. Ne-am căţărat pe soclu să nu ne lovească! Nişte tineri, mai enervaţi, au blocat unul dintre camioanele astea şi l-au răsturnat. Săreau muncitorii din camion ca puricii, aşa săreau!”, ne povesteşte Dinu Zamfirescu.

N-a durat mult nici entuziasmul său, pentru că imediat a fost arestat: „În această învălmăşeală, un tip, mai solid, m-a luat de gât, pe sus m-a luat şi m-a pus în spatele cordonului format de forţele de represiune. M-a arestat şi m-a dus la Prefectura de Poliţie, într-un beci foarte întunecos. Am fost dus apoi într-un subsol de la Academia Militară şi apoi la Jilava. O lună am stat în arest, până la 12 decembrie”. După ce a fost eliberat, Dinu Zamfirescu s-a dus direct la sediul Partidului Liberal şi a semnat adeziunea. „S-a creat prima organizaţie de elevi din cadrul unui partid politic din România – Organizaţia Colegială a Elevilor, aşa se numea”. Nu ştia atunci că, de fapt, îşi semnase încă patru condamnări la închisoare.

„Regele era un simbol pentru noi şi consideram că e o garanţie pentru salvarea României de comunişti.”

Dinu Zamfirescu
participant la miting

Mare panică au creat, printre comunişti, manifestaţiile promonarhice şi antiguvernamentale de la 8 noiembrie, iar asta se putea simţi în fiecare şedinţă sau întrunire ulterioară a Guvernului, a Partidului Comunist, a Frontului Naţional Democrat sau a Frontului Unic Muncitoresc. Mult timp a fost dezbătută „încercarea principalelor partide de răsturnare a regimului de concentrare democratică”, iar politrucii moscoviţi aruncau vina de la unul la altul.

La 9 noiembrie 1945, în şedinţa Frontului Unic Muncitoresc, Ion Burcă, reprezentantul PSD în guvern, avea pe buze soluţia perfectă: „Omoram 1.000 de oameni, dar făceam ordine. Nu trebuia să lăsăm aceste haimanele să bâţâie pe acolo. Când au văzut o forţă, o atitudine hotărâtă, s-au împrăştiat. Eu constat că Teohari (n.r. – Teohari Georgescu, ministru de Interne) s-a lăsat surprins, nu a reacţionat la timp”.

„Victimele fasciştilor manişti şi brătienişti“, comemorate ipocrit de manifestanţii comunişti Foto: fototeca online a comunismului românesc

Gheorghe Gheorghiu-Dej, cu alura sa de viitor şef de stat, vorbea voalat, în şedinţa din 10 noiembrie 1945 a Frontului Naţional Democrat, despre represiunea asupra participanţilor la miting, dar avea şi revelaţia politicii viitoare de partid. „Trebuie lucrat fără milă, să plângă cât vor, poporul trebuie să trăiască, ţara trebuie să trăiască. Dacă nu lucrăm cu sânge-rece şi dârzenie, se va râde de noi. Desigur, ruşii au destul forţe ca să-i facă chisăliţă, dar aceasta nu e de dorit şi putem evita”. Apoi, adăuga că, în urma zilei de 8 noiembrie, „ne-am trezit la realitate” – o metaforă încriptată pentru începutul campaniei represive împotriva adversarilor politic

Stratfor.com: „Assessing the Damage of the European Banking Crisis”

Text+grafica+analiza+sursa informationala: Stratfor.com

Europe faces a banking crisis it has not wanted to admit even exists.

The formal authority on financial stability, International Monetary Fund (IMF) chief Christine Lagarde, made her institution’s opinion on European banking known back in August when she prompted the European Union to engage in an immediate 200 billion-euro bank recapitalization effort. The response was broad-based derision from Europeans at the local, national and EU bureaucratic levels. The vehemence directed at Lagarde was particularly notable as Lagarde is certainly in a position to know what she was talking about: Until July 5, her title was not IMF chief, but French finance minister. She has seen the books, and the books are bad. Due to European inaction, the IMF on Oct. 18 raised its estimate for recapitalization needs from 200 billion euros to 300 billion euros ($274 billion to $410 billion).

Sovereign Debt: The Expected Problem

The collapse in early October of Franco-Belgian bank Dexia, a large Northern European institution whose demise necessitated a state rescue, shattered European confidence. Now, Europeans are discussing their banking sector. A meeting of eurozone ministers Oct. 21 is largely dedicated to the topic, as is the Oct. 23 summit of EU heads of government. Yet European governments continue to consider the banking sector largely only within the context of the ongoing sovereign debt crisis.

This is exemplified in Europeans’ handling of the Greek situation. The primary reason Greece has not defaulted on its nearly 400-billion euro sovereign debt is that the rest of the eurozone is not forcing Greece to fully implement its agreed-upon austerity measures. Withholding bailout funds as punishment would trigger an immediate default and a cascade of disastrous effects across Europe. Loudly condemning Greek inaction while still slipping Athens bailout checks keeps that aspect of Europe’s crisis in a holding pattern. In the European mind — especially the Northern European mind — a handful of small countries that made poor decisions are responsible for the European debt crisis, and while the ensuing crisis may spread to the banks as a consequence, the banks themselves would be fine if only the sovereigns could get their acts together.

This is an incorrect assumption. If anything, Europe’s banks are as damaged as the governments that regulate them.

When evaluating a problem of such magnitude, one might as well begin with the problem as the Europeans see it — namely, that their banks’ biggest problem is rooted in their sovereign debt exposure.

The state-bank contagion problem is fairly straightforward within national borders. As a rule the largest purchaser of the debt of any particular European government will be banks located in the particular country. If a government goes bankrupt or is forced to partially default on its debt, its failure will trigger the failure of most of its banks. Greece does indeed provide a useful example. Until Greece joined the European Union in 1981, state-controlled institutions dominated its banking sector. These institutions’ primary reason for being was to support government financing, regardless of whether there was a political or economic rationale justifying that financing. The Greeks, however, have no monopoly on the practice of leaning on the banking sector to support state spending. In fact, this practice is the norm across Europe.

Spain’s regional banks, the cajas, have become infamous for serving as slush funds for regional governments, regardless of the government in question’s political affiliation. Were the cajas assets held to U.S. standards of what qualifies as a good or bad loan, half the cajas would be closed immediately and another third would be placed in receivership. Italian banks hold half of Italy’s 1.9 trillion euros in outstanding state debt. And lest anyone attempt to lay all the blame on Southern Europe, French and Belgian municipalities as well as the Belgian national government regularly used the aforementioned Dexia in a somewhat similar manner.

Yet much debt remains for outsiders to own, so when states crack, the damage will not be held internally. Half or more of the debt of Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Italy and Belgium is in foreign hands, but like everything else in Europe the exposure is not balanced evenly — and this time, it is Northern Europe, not Southern Europe, that is exposed. French banks are more exposed than any other national sector, holding an amount equivalent to 8.5 percent of French gross domestic product (GDP) in the debt of the most financially distressed states (Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Italy, Belgium and Spain). Belgium comes in second with an exposure of roughly 5.5 percent of GDP, although that number excludes the roughly 45 percent of GDP Belgium’s banks hold in Belgian state debt.

When Europeans speak of the need to recapitalize their banks, creating firebreaks between cross-border sovereign debt exposure dominates their thoughts — which explains why the Europeans belatedly have seized upon the IMF’s original 200 billion-euro figure. The Europeans are hoping that if they can strike a series of deals that restructure a percentage of the debt owed by the Continent’s most financially strapped states, they will be able to halt the sovereign debt crisis in its tracks.

This plan is flawed. The figure, 200 billion euros, will not cover reasonable restructurings. The 50 percent writedowns or “haircuts” for Greece under discussion as part of a revised Greek bailout — likely to be announced at the end of the upcoming Oct. 23 EU summit — would absorb more than half of that 200 billion euros. A mere 8 percent haircut on Italian debt would absorb the remainder.

Moreover, Europe’s banking problems stretch far beyond sovereign debt. Before one can understand just how deep those problems go, we must examine the role European banks play in European society.

The Centrality of European Banking

Several differences between the European and American banking sectors exist. By far the most critical difference is that European banks are much more central to the functioning of European economies than American banks are to the U.S. economy. The reason is rooted in the geography of capital.

Maritime transport is cheaper than land transport by at least an order of magnitude once the costs of constructing road and rail infrastructure is factored in. Therefore, maritime economies will always have surplus capital compared to their land transport-based equivalents. Managing such excess capital requires banks, and so nearly all of the world’s banking centers form at points on navigable rivers where capital richness is at its most extreme. For example, New York is where the Hudson meets the Atlantic Octen, Chicago is at the southernmost extremity of the Great Lakes network, Geneva is near the head of navigation of the Rhone, and Vienna is located where the Danube breaks through the Alps-Carpathian gap.

Unity differentiates the U.S. and European banking system. The American maritime network comprises the interconnected rivers of the Greater Mississippi Basin linked into the Intracoastal Waterway, which allows for easy transport from the U.S.-Mexico border on the Gulf of Mexico all the way to the Chesapeake Bay. Europe’s maritime network is neither interlinked nor evenly shared. Northern Europe is blessed with a dozen easily navigable rivers, but none of the major rivers interconnect; each river, and thus each nation, has its own financial capital. The Danube, Europe’s longest river, drains in the opposite direction but cuts through mountains twice in doing so. Some European states have multiple navigable rivers: France and Germany each have three major ones. Arid and rugged Spain and Greece, in contrast, have none.

The unity of the American transport system means that all of its banks are interlinked, and so there is a need for a single regulatory structure. The disunity of European geography generates not only competing nationalities but also competing banking systems.

Moreover, Americans are used to far-flung and impersonal capital funding their activities (such as a bank in New York funding a project in Nebraska) because of the network’s large and singular nature. Not so in Europe. There, regional competition has enshrined banks as tools of state planning. French capital is used for French projects and other sources of capital are viewed with suspicion. Consequently, Americans only use bank loans to fund 31 percent of total private credit, with bond issuances (18 percent) and stock markets (51 percent) making up the balance. In the eurozone roughly 80 percent of private credit is bank-sourced. And instead of the United States’ single central bank, single bank guarantor and fiscal authority, Europe has dozens. Banking regulation has been expressly omitted from all European treaties to this point, instead remaining a national prerogative.

As a starting point, therefore, it must be understood that European banks are more central to the functioning of the European system than American banks are to the American system. And any problems that might erupt in the world of European banks will face a far more complicated restitution effort cluttered with overlapping, conflicting authorities colored by national biases.

Demographic Limitations

European banks also face less long-term growth. The largest piece of consumer spending in any economy is done by people in their 20s and 30s. This cohort is going to college, raising children and buying houses and cars. Yet people in their 20s and 30s are the weakest in terms of earning potential. High consumption plus low earning leads invariably to borrowing, and borrowing is banks’ mainstay. In the 1990s and 2000s much of Europe enjoyed a bulge in its population structure in precisely this young demographic — particularly in Southern European states — generating a great deal of economic activity, and from it a great deal of business for Europe’s banks.

But now, this demographic has grown up. Their earning potential has increased, while their big surge of demand is largely over, sharply curtailing their need for borrowing. In Spain and Greece, the younger end of population bulge is now 30; in Italy and France it is now 35; in Austria, Germany and the Netherlands it is 40; and in Belgium it is 45. Consumer borrowing in general and mortgage activity in particular probably have peaked. The small sizes of the replacement generations suggests there will be no recoveries within the next few decades. (Children born today will not hit their prime consumptive age for another 20 to 30 years.) With the total value of new consumer loans likely to stagnate (and more likely, decline) moving forward, if anything there are now too many European banks competing for a shrinking pool of consumer loans. Europe is thus not likely to be able to grow out of any banking problems it experiences. The one potential exception is in Central Europe, where the population bulges are on average 15 years younger than in Western Europe. The younger edge of the Polish bulge, for example, is only 25. In time, these states may be able to grow out of their problems. Either way, the most lucrative years for Western European banking are over.

Too Much Credit

Germany has extremely high capital accumulation and extremely competent economic management. One of the many results of this pairing is extremely inexpensive capital costs. When Germans — governments, corporations or individuals — borrow money, it is accepted as a near-fact that they will pay back what they owe, on time and in full. Reflecting the high supply and low risk, German borrowing rates for governments and corporations have long been in the low to mid single digits.

The further you move from Germany the less this pattern holds. Capital availability shrivels, management falters and the attitude toward contract law (or at least as defined by the Germans) becomes far less respectful. As such, Europe’s peripheral economies — most notably its smaller peripheral economies — have normally faced higher borrowing costs. Mortgage rates in Ireland stood near 20 percent less than a generation ago. Government borrowing rates in Greece have in the past topped 30 percent.

With that sort of difference, it is not difficult to see why many European states have striven for inclusion in first, the European Union, and second, the eurozone. Each step of the European integration process has brought them closer in financial terms to the ultra-low credit costs of Germany. The closer the German association, the greater the implicit belief that German financial resources would help them in a crisis (despite the fact that EU treaties explicitly rejected this).

The dawn of the eurozone era prompted lenders and investors to take this association to an extreme. Association with Germany shifted from lower lending rates to identical lending rates. The Greek government could borrow at rates that only Germany could demand in the past. Irish borrowers were able to qualify for 130 percent mortgages at 4 percent. Compounding matters, the collapse of borrowing costs and the explosion of loan activity occurred at the same time as Southern Europe’s demographic-driven consumption boom. It was the perfect storm for explosive banking growth, and it laid the groundwork for a financial collapse of unprecedented proportions.

Drastic increases in government debt are the most publicly visible outcome, but it is far from the only one. The least visible outcome is that extraordinarily cheap credit to consumers triggers an explosion in demand that local businesses cannot hope to fill. The result is unprecedented trade deficits as money borrowed from foreigners is used to purchase foreign goods. Cyprus, Greece, Portugal, Bulgaria, Romania, Lithuania, Estonia and Spain — all states whose cheap labor when compared to the Western European core should encourage them to be massive exporters — instead have run chronic trade deficits in excess of 7 percent of GDP. Most routinely broke 10 percent. Such developments do not directly harm the banks, but as credit costs return to more rational levels — and in the ongoing debt crisis borrowing costs for most of the younger EU members have tripled and more — consumption is coming to a halt. In the few European markets that demographically may be able to generate consumption-based growth in the years ahead, credit is drying up.

Foreign Currency Risk

Much of this lending into weaker locations was carried out in foreign currencies. For the three states that successfully made the early sprint into the eurozone — Estonia, Slovenia and Slovakia — this was a nonfactor. For those that did not make the early leap into the eurozone it was a wonderful way to get something for nothing. Their association with the European Union resulted in the steady strengthening of their currencies. Since 2004, the Polish, Czech, Romanian and Hungarian currencies gained roughly one-third versus the euro, driving down the monthly payments on any euro-denominated loan. That inverted, however, in the 2008 financial crisis. Then, every regional currency but the Czech koruna (and Bulgarian lev, which is pegged to the euro) gave back their gains. For Central Europeans who had taken out loans when their currencies were at their highs, payments ballooned. More than 10 percent of Polish and Hungarian mortgages are now delinquent, largely because of currency movements.

New Banking ‘Empires’

The cheap credit of the eurozone’s first decade allowed several peripheral European states a rare opportunity to expand their network of influence, even if they were not in the eurozone themselves. They could borrow money from core European banking centers like Germany, France, Switzerland and the Netherlands and pass that money on to previously credit-starved markets. In most cases, such credit was offered without the full cost-increase that these states’ poorer and smaller statures would have justified. After all, these would-be financial centers had to undercut the more established European financial centers if they were to gain meaningful market share. This pushed far more credit into Central Europe than the region otherwise would have attracted, speeding up the development process at the cost of poor underwriting and a proliferation of questionable lending practices. The most enthusiastic crafters of new banking empires have been Sweden, Austria, Spain and Greece.

  • Sweden has the happiest record of any of the states that engaged in such expansionary lending. Being one of the richest countries in Europe and yet not being a member of the eurozone, Sweden did not experience a credit expansion nearly as much as other states, instead it served as a conduit for that credit — augmented by its own — to its former imperial territories. Alone among the forgers of new banking empires, Sweden’s superior financial stability has allowed it (so far) to continue financial activities in its target markets — Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania and Denmark — despite the ongoing financial crisis. But instead of lending, Swedish banks are now purchasing regional banks outright. Swedish command of the Danish banking sector, for example, has increased by 80 percent since the crisis. Through its new local subsidiaries, Swedish banks now lend more in per capita terms to Danes than they do to their own citizens, and there is no longer a domestic Estonian banking sector — it is 97 percent Swedish-owned. Such expansionary activity is likely to continue so long as Sweden can sustain it, as there is a geopolitical angle to Sweden’s effort: It is seeking to deepen its regional influence not only for economic purposes, but also to mitigate the rising role of its longtime competitor, Russia.
  • Austria has tapped not only eurozone credit but also taken advantage of favorable carry trades to serve as a conduit for Swiss franc credit into Central Europe. Just as Sweden is using foreign capital to re-create its historic sphere of influence in the Baltic, Austria is doing the same in the lands of the former Austro-Hungarian Empire. Now, the majority of all mortgages in Poland, Hungary, Croatia and Romania — and a sizable minority in Austria — are denominated in foreign currencies, courtesy of Austrian banking activity. With the Swiss franc now locked in at record highs, many of these mortgages are not serviceable. The Hungarian government has felt forced to abrogate the terms of many of these loans, knowing that the Austrian banks are now so overexposed to Central Europe that they have no choice but to take the losses. As the financial crisis has continued apace, Austria has found itself with more exposure, fewer domestic resources and greater vulnerability to external forces than Sweden. So instead of being able to take advantage of regional weakness, it is finding itself losing market share both at home and in its would-be financial empire to Russia.
  • Spain’s banking empire isn’t even in Europe. Spanish firms BBVA-Compass and Santander have used the cheap euro credit to massively expand credit to Latin America. And Spain’s expansion took a somewhat novel route: The combination of cheap lending at home and in Latin America encouraged more than a million Latin American Spanish speakers to relocate to Spain and gain citizenship. To smooth the naturalization process, Madrid mandated that the new Spaniards be granted top-notch credit, a factor that only added to an already hyperactive construction sector. Spanish banks’ nearly 500 billion-euro exposure to Latin America is, for now, holding; only time will tell its impact to Spain’s bottom line.
  • The Greek government used its access to cheap credit to build up debt levels that are now the subject of much discussion across Europe. But much less is made of its banks, who encouraged consumers both at home and across the southern Balkans to increase their own debt levels. Being the least experienced of the four would-be financial centers, Greek banks offered the steepest credit breaks to the countries with the weakest repayment potential. Like Spain, Greece also did not make EU membership a condition for lending; vast volumes accordingly were fed into Macedonia, Serbia and even Albania.

Housing Bubbles

Large volumes of suddenly cheap credit made available to eager consumers obviously generated a series of sizable housing bubbles.

Spain’s tapping of European credit markets also underwrote the largest housing boom in Europe. More construction projects have been completed in Spain in recent years than in Germany, France, Italy and the United Kingdom combined. The construction sector — both commercial and residential — has now collapsed and there are about 1 million homes now sitting vacant in a country with just 16.5 million families. Outstanding loans to various real estate interests total some 400 billion euros, all backed by collateral that has lost 20 percent of its value since the housing market peaked.

In relative terms, Ireland actually did more than Spain. At its peak, nearly 10 percent of Irish gross national product was dependent upon construction, with 70 percent of that purely from residences. Half of the mortgages extended during the Irish real estate boom were made at the peak of the market between 2006 and 2008. That sector remains in the midst of a fairly rapid collapse. Residential home prices have reduced by half since their peak in 2007 and are showing few signs of stabilizing. The Irish government hopes that with their eurozone bailout package, their banking sector will become functional again by 2020. Until then, Ireland in effect has no banking sector and has been financially sequestered from the rest of the eurozone.

Two other European states — the United Kingdom and Sweden — have both experienced massive increases in home price growth, and both suffered from price corrections due to the 2008 financial crisis. But prices in both markets have recovered smartly, with Sweden even bouncing back above its pre-crisis highs. Sweden, in fact, is still experiencing a massive housing boom, with annual mortgage credit still expanding at a 30 percent annualized rate.

Stratfor.com: „European Crisis: Precise Solutions in an Imprecise Reality Read more: European Crisis: Precise Solutions in an Imprecise Reality”

Autor: George Friedman

Sursa informationala: Stratfor.com

An important disconnect over the discussion of the future of the European Unionexists, one that divides into three parts. First, there is the question of whether the various plans put forward in Europe plausibly could result in success given the premises they are based on. Second, there is the question of whether the premises are realistic. And third, assuming they are realistic and the plans are in fact implemented, there is the question of whether they can save the European Union as it currently exists.

The plans all are financial solutions to a particular set of financial problems. But regardless of whether they are realistic in addressing the financial problem, the question of whether the financial issue really addresses the fundamental dilemma of Europe — which is political and geopolitical — remains.

STRATFOR has examined the plans for dealing with the financial crisis in Europe, and we find them technically plausible, even if they involve navigating something of a minefield. The eurozone’s bailout fund, the European Financial Stability Facility, would be expanded in scope and reach until it can handle the bailout of a major state, the default of a minor state and a banking crisis of unprecedented proportions. Given assumptions of the magnitude of the problem and assuming general compliance with the plans, there is a chance that the solution we see the Germans moving toward could work.

The extraordinary complexity of the plans being floated in Europe is important to note. It is extremely difficult for us to understand the specifics, and we suspect the politicians proposing it are also less than clear on them. We have found that the more uncertain the solution, the more complex it is. And the complexity of the European situation is less driven by the complexity of the economics than by the complexity of the politics. The problem is relatively easy: Banks and countries under massive financial pressure almost certainly will default without extensive aid. By giving them money, default can be avoided. But the political complexity of giving them money and the opposition by many Europeans on all sides to this solution contributes to the complexity. The greater the complexity, the more interests can be satisfied and — ultimately — the less understanding there is about what has been promised. Some subjects require complexity, and this is one of them. The degree of complexity in this case tells another tale.

The Foundation of the Crisis

Part of that tale is about two dubious assumptions at the foundation of the crisis. The first is the assumption that interested parties are genuinely aware of the size of the financial problems, and to the extent they are aware of it, that they are being honest about it. Ever since 2008, the singular truth of the financial community globally has been that they were either unaware of the extent of the financial problems on the whole or unaware of the realities of their own institutions. An alternative explanation is, of course, willful ignorance. This translates as the leaders being fully aware of the magnitude of the problem but understating it to buy time or to position themselves personally for better outcomes. It could also simply be a case of their being engaged in helpless hopefulness — that is, they knew there was nothing they could do but remained hopeful that someone else would find a solution. In sum, it combined incompetence, willful deception and willful delusion.

Consider the charge that the Greeks falsified financial data. While undoubtedly true, it misses the point. The job of bankers is to analyze data from loan applicants and to uncover falsehoods. The charge against the Greeks can thus be extended to bankers. How could they not have discovered the Greek deception?

There are two answers. The first is that they didn’t want to. The global system of compensation among financial institutions — from home mortgages to the purchase of government bonds — separates the transaction from the outcome. In other words, in many cases bankers are not held responsible for the outcome of the loan and are paid for the acquisition and resale of the loan alone. They are therefore not particularly aggressive in assessing the quality of a given loan. Frequently, they work with borrowers to make their debt look more attractive.

During the U.S. subprime crisis, in the mortgage crisis in Central Europe and in the sovereign debt and banking crisis in Europe, the system placed a premium on transactions, immunizing bankers from the repayment of loans. The validity of the numbers systematically were skewed toward the most favorable case.

More important, such numbers — not only of the status of loans but also about the economic and social status of the debtors — inherently are uncertain. This is crucial because part of the proposed European solution is the imposition of austerity on debtor nation states. The specifics of that austerity and its effect on the ability to repay after austerity heavily depend on the validity of available economic and social statistics.

There is an interesting belief, at least in the advanced industrial countries, that government-issued statistics reflect reality. The idea is that the people who issued these statistics are civil servants, impervious to political pressure and therefore likely providing accurate data. A host of reasons exists for looking at national statistics with a jaundiced eye beyond the risk of politicians pressuring civil servants.

For one, collecting statistics on a society is a daunting task. Even small countries have millions of people. The national statistical database is based on the assumption that all of the transactions and productions of these millions can be measured accurately, or at least measured within some knowable range of error. This is an overwhelming undertaking.

The solution is not the actual counting of transactions — an impossible task — but the creation of statistical models that make assumptions based on various methodologies. There are competing models that provide different outcomes based on sampling procedures or mathematical models. Even without pressure from politicians, civil servants and their academic mentors have personal commitments to certain models.

The center of gravity of our global statistical system, particularly those of advanced industrial countries, is that the selection of statistical models is frequently subject to complex disputes of experts who vehemently disagree with one another. This is also a point where political pressure can be applied. Given the disagreements, the decision on which methodology to use — from sampling to reporting — is subject to political decisions because the experts are divided and as contentious as all human beings are on any subject they care about.

And this is the point at which outside decisions are made, based on outcome, not on the subtleties of mathematical modeling. There is a connection between the numbers and reality, but the mathematics of a bailout rests on a statistical base of sand. It is always assumed that this is the case in the developing world. This creates a certain advantage, in that it is understood that the statistics are unreliable. By contrast, the advanced industrial countries have the hubris to believe that complex mathematics has solved the problem of knowing what hundreds of millions of people in billions of transactions actually have done.

A Culture of Opaque States

Compounding this challenge, the European Union has incorporated societies on its periphery that never have accepted the principle that states must be transparent, a problem exacerbated by EU regulations. Southern and Central Europeans always have been less impressed by the state than Germans, for example. This is not simply about paying taxes but about a broader distrust of government, something deeply embedded in history. Meanwhile, regulations from Brussels, whose tax and employment laws make entrepreneurship and small business ownership extraordinarily difficult, have forced a good deal of the economy “off the books,” aka underground.

While not an EU state, Moldova — said to be the poorest country in Europe — is an instructive example. When I visited it a year ago, the city (and villages outside the city) was filled with banks (from Societe Generale on down) and BMWs. There was clear poverty, but there also was a wealth and vibrancy not captured in intergovernmental statistics. The numbers spoke of grinding poverty; the streets spoke of a more complex reality.

What exactly is the state of the Greek, Spanish or Italian economy? That is hard to say. Official statistics that count the legal economy suffer from methodological uncertainty. Moreover, a good deal of the economy is not included in the numbers. One assessment says that 10 percent of all employees are off the books. Another says 40 percent of Greeks define themselves as self-employed. A third estimates that 40 percent of the total Greek economy is in the grey sector. When evaluating what tries to remain hidden, you’re reduced to guesswork. No one really knows, any more than anyone really knows how many illegal immigrants are participating in the U.S. economy. The difference, however, is that this knowledge is of profound importance to the entire EU bailout.

The level of indebtedness and the ownership of the debt of European banks and countries are as murky as who held asset-backed securities in the United States. Yet there is a precise plan designed to solve a problem that can’t be quantified or allocated. The complexity and precision of the plan fails to recognize the uncertainty because the governments and banks are loath to admit that they just aren’t certain. The banks have grown so big and their relationships so complex that the uncertainty principle parallels the state’s. The United States — where the same governing authority handles all fiscal, monetary and social policies — powered through such uncertainties in the 2008 financial crisis by sheer mass and speed. Europe, with dozens of (often competing) authorities, so far has found it impossible to exercise that option.

The countries that face default and austerity have no better understanding of their own internal reality than the financial institutions understand their own internal reality. Greek numbers on the consequences of austerity for government workers do not take into account that many of those workers show up to work only occasionally while working another job that is not taxed or known to the state statistical services. Thus, one has a complete split between the state and banking systems’ ability to honor debt obligations, the insistence on austerity and the social reality of the country.

Germany has always been different. Ever since the early 19th century German philosopher Georg Hegel declared the German civil service had ended history, the idea of the state as the embodiment of reason has meant something to Germans that it did not mean to others — in both a noble and a horrible sense. We are now at the noble end of the spectrum, but the idea that the state is the embodiment of reason still doesn’t capture the European reality. The Brussels bureaucracy is based on the German view that a disinterested civil servant can produce rational solutions that partisan politicians and self-interested citizens could not.

The founding concept of the European Union involves joining nations that do not share this view, and even find it bizarre, with a nation for which it is the cultural core. This has created the fundamental existential issue in the European Union.

The realization that the rational civil servants of Brussels and Berlin have failed to create systems that understand reality strikes at German self-perceptions. There is a willful urge to retain the perception that they understand what is going on. From the standpoint of Southern and Central Europe, the realization that the Germans genuinely thought that the states on the EU periphery had reached the level of precision of the German civil services (assuming Germany had in fact reached that stage), or that they even wanted to, is a shock. Their publics, which saw the European Union as a means of getting in on German prosperity without undergoing a massive social upheaval putting the state and the civil service — disciplined and rational — at the center of their society, experienced an even greater shock.

The political and geopolitical problem is simply this: Germany is unique in Europe in terms of both size and values. It tried to create a free trade zone based on German values allied with France that looked at the world in a much more complex way. The crisis we are seeing, which Germany is trying to solve with extraordinary complexity and precision, rests on a highly unstable base. First, the European banking system, like the American banking system, does not understand its status. Second, the entire mathematics of national statistics is inherently imprecise. Third, the peripheral countries of the European Union have economies that cannot be measured at all because their informal economies are massive. The fundamental principles and self-conception of Germany and Central Europe diverge massively. The elites of these countries might like to think of themselves as Europeans first — by the German definition — but the publics know they are not, and they don’t want to be.

The precision of the bailout schemes reveals the underlying misunderstanding of reality by Europe’s elites, and specifically by the Germans. To be more precise, this is willful misunderstanding. They all know that their precision rests on a foundation of uncertainty. They are buying time hoping that prosperity will return, mooting all of these problems. But the problem is that a precise solution to a vastly uncertain problem is unlikely to return Europe to its happy past. Reality — or rather the fundamental unreality of Europe — has returned.

In some sense, this is no different from the United States and China. But the United States has its Constitution and the Civil War’s consequences to hold itself together in the face of this problem, and China has the Communist Party’s security apparatus to give it a shot. Europe, by contrast, has nothing to hold it together but the promise of prosperity and the myth of the rational civil servant — the cultural and political side of the underlying geopolitical problem.

Stratfor.com: „The Crisis of Europe and European Nationalism”

Sursa informationala: Stratfor.com

Autor: George Friedman

When I visited Europe in 2008 and before, the idea that Europe was not going to emerge as one united political entity was regarded as heresy by many leaders. The European enterprise was seen as a work in progress moving inevitably toward unification — a group of nations committed to a common fate. What was a core vision in 2008 is now gone. What was inconceivable — the primacy of the traditional nation-state — is now commonly discussed, and steps to devolve Europe in part or in whole (such as ejecting Greece from the eurozone) are being contemplated. This is not a trivial event.

Before 1492, Europe was a backwater of small nationalities struggling over a relatively small piece of cold, rainy land. But one technological change made Europe the center of the international system: deep-water navigation.

The ability to engage in long-range shipping safely allowed businesses on the Continent’s various navigable rivers to interact easily with each other, magnifying the rivers’ capital-generation capacity. Deep-water navigation also allowed many of the European nations to conquer vast extra-European empires. And the close proximity of those nations combined with ever more wealth allowed for technological innovation and advancement at a pace theretofore unheard of anywhere on the planet. As a whole, Europe became very rich, became engaged in very far-flung empire-building that redefined the human condition and became very good at making war. In short order, Europe went from being a cultural and economic backwater to being the engine of the world.

At home, Europe’s growing economic development was exceeded only by the growing ferocity of its conflicts. Abroad, Europe had achieved the ability to apply military force to achieve economic aims — and vice versa. The brutal exploitation of wealth from some places (South America in particular) and the thorough subjugation and imposed trading systems in others (East and South Asia in particular) created the foundation of the modern order. Such alternations of traditional systems increased the wealth of Europe dramatically.

But “engine” does not mean “united,” and Europe’s wealth was not spread evenly. Whichever country was benefitting had a decided advantage in that it had greater resources to devote to military power and could incentivize other countries to ally with it. The result ought to have been that the leading global empire would unite Europe under its flag. It never happened, although it was attempted repeatedly. Europe remained divided and at war with itself at the same time it was dominating and reshaping the world.

The reasons for this paradox are complex. For me, the key has always been the English Channel. Domination of Europe requires a massive land force. Domination of the world requires a navy heavily oriented toward maritime trade. No European power was optimized to cross the channel, defeat England and force it into Europe. The Spanish Armada, the French navy at Trafalgar and the Luftwaffe over Britain all failed to create the conditions for invasion and subjugation. Whatever happened in continental Europe, the English remained an independent force with a powerful navy of its own, able to manipulate the balance of power in Europe to keep European powers focused on each other and not on England (most of the time). And after the defeat of Napoleon, the Royal Navy created the most powerful empire Europe had seen, but it could not, by itself, dominate the Continent. (Other European geographic features obviously make unification of Europe difficult, but all of them have, at one point or another, been overcome. Except for the channel.)

Underlying Tensions

The tensions underlying Europe were bought to a head by German unification in 1871 and the need to accommodate Germany in the European system, of which Germany was both an integral and indigestible part. The result was two catastrophic general wars in Europe that began in 1914 and ended in 1945 with the occupation of Europe by the United States and the Soviet Union and the collapse of the European imperial system. Its economy shattered and its public plunged into a crisis of morale and a lack of confidence in the elites, Europe had neither the interest in nor appetite for empire.

Europe was exhausted not only by war but also by the internal psychosis of two of its major components. Hitler’s Germany and Stalin’s Soviet Union might well have externally behaved according to predictable laws of geopolitics. Internally, these two countries went mad, slaughtering both their own citizens and citizens of countries they occupied for reasons that were barely comprehensible, let alone rationally explicable. From my point of view, the pressure and slaughter inflicted by two world wars on both countries created a collective mental breakdown.

I realize this is a woefully inadequate answer. But consider Europe after World War II. First, it had gone through about 450 years of global adventure and increasingly murderous wars, in the end squandering everything it had won. Internally, Europe watched a country like Germany — in some ways the highest expression of European civilization — plunge to levels of unprecedented barbarism. Finally, Europe saw the United States move from the edges of history to assume the role of an occupying force. The United States became the envy of the Europeans: stable, wealthy, unified and able to impose its economic, political and military will on major powers on a different continent. (The Russians were part of Europe and could be explained within the European paradigm. So while the Europeans may have disdained the Russians, the Russians were still viewed as poor cousins, part of the family playing by more or less European rules.) New and unprecedented, the United States towered over Europe, which went from dominance to psychosis to military, political and cultural subjugation in a twinkling of history’s eye.

Paradoxically, it was the United States that gave the first shape to Europe’s future, beginning with Western Europe. World War II’s outcome brought the United States and Soviet Union to the center of Germany, dividing it. A new war was possible, and the reality and risks of the Cold War were obvious. The United States needed a united Western Europe to contain the Soviets. It created NATO to integrate Europe and the United States politically and militarily. This created the principle of transnational organizations integrating Europe. The United States also encouraged economic cooperation both within Europe and between North America and Europe — in stark contrast to the mercantilist imperiums of recent history — giving rise to the European Union’s precursors. Over the decades of the Cold War, the Europeans committed themselves to a transnational project to create a united Europe of some sort in a way not fully defined.

There were two reasons for this thrust for unification. The first was the Cold War and collective defense. But the deeper reason was a hope for a European resurrection from the horrors of the 20th century. It was understood that German unification in 1871 created the conflicts and that the division of Germany in 1945 re-stabilized Europe. At the same time, Europe did not want to remain occupied or caught in an ongoing near-war situation. The Europeans were searching for a way to overcome their history.

One problem was the status of Germany. The deeper problem was nationalism. Not only had Europe failed to unite under a single flag via conquest but also World War I had shattered the major empires, creating a series of smaller states that had been fighting to be free. The argument was that it was nationalism, and not just German nationalism, that had created the 20th century. Europe’s task was therefore to overcome nationalism and create a structure in which Europe united and retained unique nations as cultural phenomena and not political or economic entities. At the same time, by embedding Germany in this process, the German problem would be solved as well.

A Means of Redemption

The European Union was designed not simply to be a useful economic tool but also to be a means of European redemption. The focus on economics was essential. It did not want to be a military alliance, since such alliances were the foundation of Europe’s tragedy. By focusing on economic matters while allowing military affairs to be linked to NATO and the United States, and by not creating a meaningful joint-European force, the Europeans avoided the part of their history that terrified them while pursuing the part that enticed them: economic prosperity. The idea was that free trade regulated by a central bureaucracy would suppress nationalism and create prosperity without abolishing national identity. The common currency — the euro — is the ultimate expression of this hope. The Europeans hoped that the existence of some Pan-European structure could grant wealth without surrendering the core of what it means to be French or Dutch or Italian.

Yet even during the post-World War II era of security and prosperity, some Europeans recoiled from the idea of a transfer of sovereignty. The consensus that many in the long line of supporters of European unification believed existed simply didn’t. And today’s euro crisis is the first serious crisis that Europe has faced in the years since, with nationalism beginning to re-emerge in full force.

In the end, Germans are Germans and Greeks are Greeks. Germany and Greece are different countries in different places with different value systems and interests. The idea of sacrificing for each other is a dubious concept. The idea of sacrificing for the European Union is a meaningless concept. The European Union has no moral claim on Europe beyond promising prosperity and offering a path to avoid conflict. These are not insignificant goals, but when the prosperity stops, a large part of the justification evaporates and the aversion to conflict (at least political discord) begins to dissolve.

Germany and Greece each have explanations for why the other is responsible for what has happened. For the Germans, it was the irresponsibility of the Greek government in buying political power with money it didn’t have to the point of falsifying economic data to obtain eurozone membership. For the Greeks, the problem is the hijacking of Europe by the Germans. Germany controls the eurozone’s monetary policy and has built a regulatory system that provides unfair privileges, so the Greeks believe, for Germany’s exports, economic structure and financial system. Each nation believes the other is taking advantage of the situation.

Political leaders are seeking accommodation, but their ability to accommodate each other is increasingly limited by public opinion growing more hostile not only to the particulars of the deal but to the principle of accommodation. The most important issue is not that Germany and Greece disagree (although they do, strongly) but that their publics are increasingly viewing each other as nationals of a foreign power who are pursuing their own selfish interests. Both sides say they want “more Europe,” but only if “more Europe” means more of what they want from the other.

Managing Sacrifice

Nationalism is the belief that your fate is bound up with your nation and your fellow citizens and you have an indifference to the fate of others. What the Europeanists tried to do was create institutions that made choosing between your own and others unnecessary. But they did this not with martial spirit or European myth, which horrified them. They made the argument prudently: You will like Europe because it will be prosperous, and with all of Europe prosperous there will be no need to choose between your nation and other nations. Their greatest claim was that Europe would not require sacrifice. To a people who lived through the 20th century, the absence of sacrifice was enormously seductive.

But, of course, prosperity comes and goes, and as it goes sacrifice is needed. And sacrifice — like wealth — is always unevenly distributed. That uneven distribution is determined not only by necessity but also by those who have power and control over institutions. From a national point of view, it is Germany and France that have the power, with the British happy to be out of the main fray. The weak are the rest of Europe, those who surrendered core sovereignty to the Germans and French and now face the burdens of managing sacrifice.

In the end, Europe will remain an enormously prosperous place. The net worth of Europe — its economic base, its intellectual capital, its organizational capabilities — is stunning. Those qualities do not evaporate. But crisis reshapes how they are managed, operated and distributed. This is now in question. Obviously, the future of the euro is now widely discussed. So the future of the free-trade zone will come to the fore. Germany is a massive economy by itself, exporting more per year than the gross domestic products of most of the world’s other nation-states. Does Greece or Portugal really want to give Germany a blank check to export what it wants with it, or would they prefer managed trade under their control? Play this forward past the euro crisis and the foundations of a unified Europe become questionable.

This is the stuff that banks and politicians need to worry about. The deeper worry is nationalism. European nationalism has always had a deeper engine than simply love of one’s own. It is also rooted in resentment of others. Europe is not necessarily unique in this, but it has experienced some of the greatest catastrophes in history because of it. Historically, the Europeans have hated well. We are very early in the process of accumulating grievances and remembering how to hate, but we have entered the process. How this is played out, how the politicians, financiers and media interpret these grievances, will have great implications for Europe. Out of it may come a broader sense of national betrayal, which was just what the European Union was supposed to prevent.

PNL, NOUL INCEPUT

Crin Antonescu: „Suntem un partid naţional şi liberal dar definim mai altfel şi interesul naţional şi liberalismul, decât o fac scamatorii care ne conduc în prezent.” (Bucuresti, 6 septembrie 2011)

PNL, NOUL INCEPUT

PNL-ul revine in viata politica a Romaniei in ianuarie 1990 ca rezultat al initiativei din 22 decembrie 1989 al unui grup de veterani ai partidului in frunte cu Dan A. Lazarescu, Nicu Enescu si Ionel V Sandulescu. Alaturi de ei se mai gaseau si alti vechi liberali intre care trebuie amintit verticalul si intransigentul Sorin Botez, Dinu Zamfirescu, unul din liderii exilului romanesc, fostul presedinte al studentilor liberali, Radu Campeanu, fostul presedinte TNL Prahova, Mircea Ionescu-Quintus si multi altii.

Spre deosebire de PNT-CD care pastra in fruntea sa un nucleu dur al vechiului grup din jurul lui Maniu si Mihalache, pornind de la secretarul lui Iuliu Maniu, Corneliu Coposu ,Seniorul politicii romanesti de dupa 1989, ,,presedintele moral,, al Romaniei dupa cum a fost supranumit si apoi liderii tineretului national-taranesc de dinainte de 1947 cum ar fi Ion Diaconescu, Nicolae Ionescu-Galbeni, Gabriel Tepelea, Ion Puiu ,fratii Boila, apoi Ion Ratiu, proaspat revenit din exil, PNL-ul reusea o coagulare mai greoaie la nivel de varf. Ion Bratianu, fiul lui Gheorghe Bratianu si Dan Bratianu, fiul lui Constantin I.C. Bratianu murisera cu cativa ani inainte de revolutie iar Vintila Bratianu jr. din cauza problemelor de sanatate si de familie va rata revenirea in tara in acel tulbure ianuarie 1990.

Nu trebuie uitat insa faptul ca dupa asasinarea lui Duca in 1933 se inregistreaza reculul lent dar sigur al PNL, sub loviturile lui Carol al-II-lea aplicate prin intermediul lui Guta Tatarescu.

Pana in 1928, PNL-ul dominase autoritar viata publica romaneasca, dar incepand cu anii 30 va traversa un process de eroziune care va face din PNT in cursul anilor 40, partid mult mai incoerent ideologic, dar cu o priza deosebita in randul maselor populare, principalul simbol al rezistentei nationale impotriva sovietizarii tarii.

La alegerile din 1946 procentul voturilor obtinute in mod real de PNL chiar si fara frauda era unul mult mic (cca. 18%) decat cel al PNT, partid care in realitate castigase alegerile cu un detasat 60%.

Represiunea comunista a avut ca principal tinta PNT, partid care pornise ca principal vector politic pe partea de centru si centru-stanga si care asemeni PSDR, dar si miscarilor dreptei radicale era un partid catch-all-over, ceea ce PNL nu a fost niciodata.

Si dupa crunta represiune comunista, multa mai tanarul PNT (infiintat in 1926 ), mai degraba un compozit la prima vedere bizar intre burghezia nationala greco-catolica din Ardeal si stanga non-marxista taraneasca din Valahia, se profila ca principal adversar al fortelor FSN controlate de esaloanele inferioare ale PCR si de Securitate.

Spre deosebire de PNL, PNT activase si in ilegalitate si nu trebuie uitat ca in 1987 Corneliu Coposu, inscrisese prin intermediul lui Dorin Reichel, partidul in Internationala Crestin Democrata.

PNL –ul insa ,deja fragilizat de Carol Caraiman si dictaturile ce i-au urmat acestuia pana in 1990, se reunise sub imboldul lui Dan A. Lazarescu si la primul congres din 1990 avea sa-si aleaga un presedinte in persoana lui Radu Campeanu, venit dupa un lung exil la Paris.

Mesajul politic al PNL, spre deosebire de cel al PNT, desi in cateva puncte mari- anticomunism, restituirea proprietatilor, atasamentul fata de monarhie si raportarea la valorile traditionale ale societatii romanesti interbelice – era oarecum diferit. Astfel ca PNL –ul punea un accent deosebit pe factorul economic si pe elemente ce sustin o economie de tip liberal: privatizari, incurajarea capitalului privat, dereglementarea economiei de tip etatist de la acea data la care sa adaugau separarea puterilor in stat, democratizarea institutionala, reforma administrativa si juridica, elemente ce dadeau PNL-ului un aer ceva mai pragmatic si dinamic in acest orizont gri de dupa 1989.

PNT –ul sustinea deasemeni si el reatasarea Romaniei la aliatii occidentali, poate cu o fervoare mai mare decat PNL si PSDR.

Dar totodata anticomunismul PNT-CD este unul care doreste luarea de masuri legale pentru pedepsirea aspra a celor care se faceau vinovati de represiunea comunista, doar fusese cel mai oropsit partid istoric. Acest lucru era sustinut si de celelalte partide istorice, dar nu cu aceeasi fermitate precum se intampla in discursul PNT-CD. Totodata dimensiunea morala juca un rol deosebit in viziunea politica a PNT-CD alaturi de repararea masurilor luate de puterea de dupa 1948, de tematica legata de Biserica si culte, dar si de reforma fondului funciar.

Desi la alegerile din mai 1990 PNL obtinuse un scor promitator in ciuda unei victorii categorice a lui Ion Iliescu si FSN, acest fapt nu va reusi sa transforme partidul in forta motrica a opozitiei anticomuniste romanesti. Unul din vechiile neajunsuri ale liberalismului romanesc il reprezinta dezbinarea, astfel ca drumul de la un partid care punea argumentat piciorul in pragul regimului FSN la usa din dosul parlamentului nu va fi foarte lung. Intre 1990-1992 PNL a adoptat tactica unei ,,opozitii constructive,, spre deosebire de PNT-CD care dupa un sever esec in alegeri mersese pe cartea confruntarii fatise cu regimul autoritarist de tip ,,perestroika,, patronat de Iliescu.

Boala sciziunilor si fractiunilor va lovi aspru PNL-ul astfel ca la alegerile din 1992 pe langa batranul partid successor al Bratienilor vom avea PNL-AT, PNL-CD, PAC, ULB, NPL si alte formule mai mult ori mai putin national-liberale care vor duce la faramitarea electoratului liberal si care vor slabi puternic structurile PNL.

Dinu Patriciu a jucat un rol deosebit de important in cadrul acestei intregi pleiade de urmasi ai vechilor ,,fractionisti”, ,,drapelisti” ori ,,moderati” de pe vremea lui Caragiale, gen Guna Vernescu si Nicolae Fleva, Patriciu pornind neuitata ,,aripa tanara,, in care dorea sa aspire tot suflul nou al PNL si care s-a aflat in afara partidului sub numele de PL 93 pana in 1997, fiind la un moment dat un competitor exigent al PNL-ului pe culoarul national-liberal.

PNL-ul avea sa acceada in guvernul Stolojan (1991-1992) cu 3 ministere intre care si justitia unde titular a fost viitorul presedinte al partidului, Mircea Ionescu Quintus. PNL nu are spre deosebire de PNT-CD vocatia unui partid de lupta sociala ori a unui partid anti-sistem,ci este prin traditie si menire un partid de guvernare, un partid mai degraba de cadre, o structura politica deschisa dialogului si creatoare de institutii, si accentuez acest fapt care dovedeste falsitatea unei teze pe care am neplacerea sa o aud de la unii din colegii nostri, aceea cum ca PNL-ul a fost un partid de stanga. PNL nu se declineaza din bateria de idei al “Manifestului Comunist”, iar sigla PNL a fost “Sageata Liberal” si nu “Garoafa Socialista”, simbolul vesnic al stangii europene.

Poate ca am fost asezati la stanga conservatorismului clasic din era junimismului, aceasta prin deschiderea fata de reformele sociale si fata de emanciparea muncitorilor si taranilor, dar niciodata nu am fost un adevarat partid de stanga. PNL a fost dintotdeauna un partid creator de natiune si de institutii solide, un partid cu adanci radacini nationale si cu spirit de sacrificiu pe altarul valorilor identitare ale spiritului romanesc, de aceea liberalismul conservator este pecetea doctrinara a adevaratului liberal roman, fie el mai radical ori mai moderat.

Tocmai acest spirit deschis dezbaterii si cu ispita nuantelor suplimentare care generase o forma de coabitare cu FSN-ul, spre deosebire de radicalism si ,,ascetismul,, purtatorilor de mesaj national-taranisti, vor face ca principalele energii anticomuniste sa se indrepte spre PNT-CD in jurul caruia avea sa se creeze viitoarea Conventie Democrata Romana ( CDR ).

La 26 noiembrie 1991 se infiintase CDR, cu PNL printre membri fondatori, dar care in urma unor divergente intre Radu Campeanu si liderii PNT-CD,va fi parasit de PNL in aprilie 1992.

O alta manevra care va slabi puternic partidul, va fi propunerea presedintelui PNL facuta Regelui Mihai, ca acesta sa candideze la functia de presedinte al Romaniei in toamna lui 1992.

Toate aceste miscari vor rezulta intr-un scor dezastruos al partidului si iesirea acestuia din randurile parlamentului. Divizat, scindat, lipsit de coeziune, PNL se gasea intr-un punct ce parea a fi drumul spre istorie si ramanerea definitive acolo. Insa vocile din partid ce aveau sa ceara revenirea in CDR si reconstructia partidului sfasiat de sciziuni, care deseori se datorau unor orgolii stupide ori unor urzeli ale puterii autoritariste, aveau sa se inteteasca si congresul de la Brasov din 1993 avea sa aduca o serie de schimbari importante in structurile partidului si in viziunea sa politica. Atunci are loc revenirea in partid a liberalilor mai tineri din randurile Nouui Partid Liberal, de fapt un grup de dizidenti ce revenea in partid dup ace se lepadasera de mirajul, “aripii tinere,, a lui Patriciu, care tot atunci devenea PL 93.

E drept PL93 si PAC reusesira sa prinda trenul parlamentar sub aripa larga a CDR. CDR polarizase in jurul sau aproape tot ce insemna curentul democratic si anticommunist dornic de schimbare in Romania de la aceea data.

Radu Campeanu pierde conducerea partidului in favoarea lui Mircea Ionescu Quintus ,ceea ce va duce la un lung litigiu si la un drum prin desertul politicii al lui Radu Campeanu, de altfel un om politic energic si educat in spiritul Romaniei interbelice care va reveni la PNL dupa cativa ani de stearpa dizidenta fiind probabil unul din cei mai buni senatori liberali ai legislaturii 2004-2008.

Schimbarea la varf a fost de bun augur partidului, generand aceea emulatie si intremare a fortelor liberale pe care fostul presedinte nu o mai putea genera. Noua conducere era o imbinare intre vechi si nou, probabil ceea mai fericita din toti acesti ani post-revolutionari ai PNL, pe de-o parte aveam clarviziunea, nobletea spirituala si devotamentul unora precum presedintele Ionescu Quintus , Dan A. Lazarescu, Sorin Bottez ori Ioana Bratianu, fiica lui Gheorghe Bratianu si nepoata directa lui Ion I.C. Bratianu iar pe cealalta parte dinamismul, energia si dorinta de afirmare a unora precum Calin Popescu Tariceanu, Radu Boroianu si nu in ultimul rand a controversatului om de afaceri Viorel Catarama, cel care in ciuda unei formatii nu foarte solide si mai ales a unei relatii niciodata clarificata cu structurile fostei securitatii, avea sa fie cel care va conduce discutiile de reafiliere a PNL la CDR in anul 1995, intr-un mod foarte avantaj pentru partid.

Astfel ca la alegerile din 1996, castigate de candidatul CDR, Emil Constantinescu, PNL avea sa revina in parlament cu 17 senatori si 27 de deputati, dovada a reusitei lui Mircea Ionescu Quintus si ale grupului aflat atunci la conducere de a strange in jurul lor oameni cu adevarat angajati in planul ideilor liberale si dornici de a pune in valoare un proiect national axat pe principiile liberalismului romanesc.

Intrat la guvernare, dar fiind doar a treia vioara in guvernele Ciorbea, Radu Vasile si Isarescu, dupa PNT-CD si PD, PNL va definitiva ceea ce se numeste ca fiind ,,marea reunificare liberala,,, proces care se va incheia dupa inghitirea structurilor PL 93 (Patriciu) si PAC (Nicolae Manolescu) in anul 1998.

Dan A. Lazarescu spunea in acest punct, dupa ce cu mici exceptii toate partidele liberale afiliate la CDR se regasisera sub sageata PNL-ului ca nu mai poate fi vorba de nicio fuziune si nici vreo ,,reunificare,,. Din pacate afirmatiile inteleptului batran liberal aveau sa fie contrazise de verosul Valeriu Stoica, steaua ascendenta a partidului, ministru al justitiei care dupa 1997 va incerca sa controleze intreg partidul din pozitia de secund al lui Ionescu Quintus.

Calin Popescu Tariceanu va fi o bucata de timp ministru al industriilor iar Crin Antonescu ministru al tineretului si sportului, cei doi lideri liberali fiind alaturi de nume precum Mona Musca ori Andrei Chiliman cateva din figurile care se afirma tot mai intens dupa 1997 in PNL.

In aceasta perioada de guvernare vechile conflicte mocnite intre PNL si PNT-CD care vor duce la o ruptura finala in anul 2000, cand PNL va candida din nou pe liste proprii. PNL-ul se intarise, dar o data cu Stoica drumul consolidarii ideologice si structural in jurul elitelor ,,mari,, si ,,mici,, a paturilor dinamice si instruite din urban, fara a neglija zonele conservatoare din rural, dar pastrand o pondere simtitoare mediului intelectual romanesc avea sa se impotmoleasca.

Viziunea lui Stoica era axata pe o linie oportunisto-arivista ce sustinea extinderea partidului atat spre dreapta cat si spre stanga. In acesti ani PNL-ul, sub influenta gandirii lui Stoica incepe sa atraga o serie de personaje venite din spatiul fesenist si chiar criptocomunist care se vor asimila cu greu spiritului liber si mai degraba rebel al marii parti a liberalilor romani.

Ruptura de PNT-CD, partid care in ciuda unor valori morale autentice si a unui atasament deosebit fata de ideea de democratie, avea sa plateasca pe de-a intregul si pot spune pe nedrept nota de plata a guvernarii CDR, va aduce pentru PNL o serie de asocieri ciudate.

Traian Basescu fusese cel sabotase in chip securist guvernarea CDR-USD-UDMR si care se erijase intr-un lider populist, el era de faptul unul din oamenii vechiului sistem care au jucat un rol important in demantelarea tentivelor partidelor istorice de a reforma structural Romania. Greul guvernari cazuse pe taranisti, iar intreg discursul public se refugiase spre culoarul de stanga.

In PNL strategia Stoica incepea sa-si arate, ,rezultatele,, astfel ca in partid au fost atrasi o serie de personalitati de coloratura social-liberala cum s-a declarat si care au format ,,Initiativa Social Liberala,, condusa de enigmaticul Teodor Stolojan, fost casier al visteriei securitatii in relatia cu Ceausescu, fost prim-ministru FSN ramas celebru pentru nationalizarea valutei si plecat apoi pe un post de expert la Banca Mondiala. Fostul technocrat comunist beneficia din plin de imaginea aceea favorabila pe care papusarii cu ,,ochi albastri“ au stiut dintotdeauna s-o construiasca in jurul unor false personalitati providentiale.

Virajul spre stanga era unul evident, linia nationala, pro-monarhista, elitista ori filoantreprenoriala devenise un ,,vis” in discursul politic al celui care monopolizase imaginea PNL.

Stoica, omul care din 2000 l-a implantat pe Stolojan in randurile PNL. Aducerea lui Stolojan va tulbura apele in partid, nemultumiri si critici puternice venind din partea unor personalitati autentic liberale precum Dan A. Lazarescu, Sorin Botez ori Dinu Zamfirescu. La alegerile din octombrie 2000, un PNL pe liste proprii, cu un candidat de presedinte T. Stolojan iesit abia pe locul 3, in ciuda popularitatii din jurul numelui sau, va obtine 13 senatori si 30 de deputati, cca. 9 % din totalul locurilor in Parlament.

PNT-CD, celalalt mare partid istoric, un partid de cuprindere mai larga decat PNL, cu un discurs mai direct, dar mai putin adaptabil si mai lipsit de coeziune administrativa si institutionala, pe fondul decontarii nerealizarilor guvernarii 1996-2000 ,va parasi Parlamentul dup ace candidase pe listele CDR 2000, o alianta neispirata, daca mergeau singuri, taranistii reuseau sa ramana pe intaia scena politica unde le era locul . Din pacate misiunea vechii si noii securitati de distrugere a partidelor istorice, parea, cel putin pe jumatate, ca reuseste !

In 2001, Stoica devine oficial lider al PNL, se facea astfel un schimb definitiv de generatii iar sforarul care credea ca pentru orice castig imediat merita jucat la ruleta cu identitatea partidului ajungea lider. Generatia lui Ionescu Quintus joaca si astazi un rol simbolic si consultativ in partid, oamenii precum el si ultimii sai colegi de generatie sunt cei prin care suntem legitimi si cei care tin carma morala a national liberalismului asa cum il avem de la Bratieni.

Politica tandemului Stoica-Stolojan de transformare a PNL intr-un partid compozit si de aglutinare a identitatii national-liberale va continua. In 2001, PNL semneaza un protocol nefericit de sprijin guvernamental cu PSD, protocol din fericire nefinalizat. Apoi in 2002 are loc fuziunea un grupusculul ApR, desprins din PDSR in 1997, aflat sub conducerea fostului ministru de externe al PDSR intre 1992-1996, Teodor Melescanu.

Din cauza nemultumirilor iscate in partid, Stoica ii va lasa locul in urma unui congres extraordinar in anul 2002 lui Stolojan, care devine presedinte al PNL. In 2003 PNL va absoarbe o alta formatiune politica, de data asta de dreapta, UFD-ul condus de Varujan Vosganian.

Stolojan nu s-a comportat niciodata ca un adevarat liberal si perioada sa la conducerea partidului are o serie de caracteristici bizare: conducere centralizata si autoritara, lipsa de comunicare ,impunerea unei clientele exterioare partidului in functii cheie, promovare de lideri falsi fara substanta in unele organizatii, cultul liderului si nu in ultimul rand acceptarea unei aliante cu PD-ul in curs de dezintegrare si condus de un Basescu haituit de PSD ,pe fondul unei cresteri a PNL-ului in optiunile electoratului.

Desi Stolojan si Basescu nu s-au agreat niciodata ca la ,,un semn,, si-au dat mana in septembrie 2003 sub sigla aliantei ,,Dreptate si Adevar,, (DA), alianta creata cu scopul infrangerii in alegeri a PSD si a lui Adrian Nastase, cel care deja se vedea urmasul lui Iliescu la Cotroceni, revolutia portocalie urma in plan romanesc sa fie triumful unei puteri non-ideologice ce marca sfarsitul ultimului partid istoric de pe prima scena a politicii romanesti, intre timp si PSDR-ul fusese inghitit de PDSR care dupa 2001 devine PSD.

Alianta DA garanta locuri pe liste mai degraba acolitilor lui Stolojan deloc familiarizati cu valorile national-liberalismului nostrum traditional si care aveau o viziune strict practica si utilitarista, iar colac peste pupaza PNL avea sa accepte oferirea PD-ului pe liste unui raport de 1,3 la 1 desi in sondaje PNL avea cel putin dublul scorului avut de grupul ramas inca in jurul figurii histrionice a lui Basescu.

La alegerile din noiembrie 2004, PSD va castiga 37%, iar alianta DA doar 32 %, insa in turul 2 Basescu il invinge pe Nastase, iar succesiunea Iliescu-Nastase extrem de fireasca cu 2-3 luni inainte conform tuturor estimarilor nu se mai produce.

Sa nu uitam insa episodul abandonului lui Stolojan in fata lui Basescu din toamna lui 2004, jocul melodramatic jucat dupa toate regulile nescrise si scrise ale manipularii. Stolojan isi jucase bine rolul, mai ramanea ca Basescu sa castige alegerile si apoi partidul nostru sa fie impins spre o fuziune fortata cu PD ce avea ca scop eliminarea de pe scena politica a PNL, visul neimplinit nici astazi al multora din cei care doresc ca politica romaneasca sa fie un joc fals si ieftin intre un FSN de stanga si un FSN de dreapta.

Presedintele nou ales, T. Basescu printr-o manevra reuseste impunerea unui guvern PNL-PD-PC-UDMR in fruntea caruia se gasea noul presedinte al PNL, Calin Popescu Tariceanu, primul prim ministru liberal al Romaniei dupa o pauza de 67 de ani!

Luna de miere a relatiei PNL-PD, respectiv Basescu-Tariceanu se incheie rapid. Basescu facandu-si din subminarea si subordonarea PNL principalul sau obiectiv politic. Tariceanu va evita cu abilitate cursa intinsa in vara lui 2005 in vederea declansarii alegerilor alegerilor anticipate si apoi va tergiversa pana la saturatie proiectul fuziunii PNL-PD, care isi va arata adevaratul scop in toamna lui 2006 cand un grup de ,liberali,, patronati de tandemul Stoica-Stolojan paraseste partidul si se pune pres la picioarele lui Basescu formand asa numitul „Partid Liberal Democrat PLD”.

De aici incolo antagonismul cu puterea autoritarist-oligarhica a lui Basescu, epigon marunt al modelul postsovietic de tip putinian, este una din liniile directorii ale guvernarii Tariceanu, guvernare care dupa aprilie 2007 pana in noirmbrie 2008 va fi una minoritara PNL-UDMR (20% sustinere parlamentara) dar cu sprijin PSD pe anumite legi si proiecte.

Guvernarea Tariceanu a avut 2 principale coordonate: rezistenta fata de presiuniile si interventiile lui Basescu care isi facuse din daramarea guvernului liberal principalul obiectiv politic pe de-o partea si cresterea bunastarii publice in planul concret al activitatii guvernamentale.

Guvernarea 2004-2008 reprezinta un success in planul politicilor liberale bazate pe o reducere a fiscalitatii si pe introducerea cotei unice, pe non-interventia in economie si pe atragerea de investitii directe in industrie si servicii dar si pe lansarea unor proiecte concrete de investitii publice . Cresterea economica din acesti ani de reala bunastare a putut permite guvernului si o redistribuire a acestei plus-valori spre pensionari dupa anul 2007. Guvernarea PNL coincide si cu varful cresterii economice a Romaniei de dupa 1989, varf datorat si unor elemente ce tin de ordinal capitalului international speculativ care este atras de Romania dupa 2006 mai ales si care pe fondul crizei economice globale va parasi rapid pietele noastre interne dupa 2008, dar si unui climat economic pe care guvernarile CDR-PSD-PNL din intervalul 1999-2008 au stiut sa-l intretina in contextul atragerii de investitii si fonduri externe generate de expansiunea pietele economice europene de la cumpana dintre cele 2 milenii.

In rest aceeasi perioada coincide si incheierea procesului de aderare a Romaniei la UE la 1 ianuarie 2007, UE era perceputa atunci ca un panacea universal la problemele romanilor, intre timp criza economica si formula etatista si birocratica a proiectului de la Bruxelles incepe sa-si arate limitele sub loviturile crizei mondiale.

Basescu controla riguros tot ce insemna in acei ani structura de forta ori institutie de tip statal strict ierarhizata iar capacitatea unui guvern aflat sub o presiune permanenta din partea Cotrocenilor si minoritar de a pune la punct politici nationale extinse, de a se implica in promovarea externa a interselor Romaniei ori de a porni politici menite sa democratizeze Romania din punct de vedere structural era una extreme de redusa. Guvernarea PNL a fost una in regim de avarie si sub amenintarea constanta a ,,sabiei,, prezidentiale. Dar cu toate acestea, Calin Popescu Tariceanu si-a incheiat mandatul la termen. In noiembrie 2008, un PNL atacat din toate directiile trecea in opozitie dupa ce obtinea un satisfacator rezultat de 19 %, reprezentant 93 de mandate parlamentare in alegerile legislative unde candidase pe listele sale.

PNL rezistase lui Basescu si PD (PD-L intre timp) printr-o buna disciplina de actiune, printr-o abila parghie administrative si prin capacitate de motivare. Dar guvernarea DA, apoi cea minoritara adusesera si o serie de neajunsuri in interiorul partidului, mai ales dupa indepartarea primului ministru de baza partidului dar si dupa o linie de guvernamant pe care unii liberali o considerau prea diluata cand o priveau de pe pozitii de dreapta, erodasera capitalul de imagine si forta al lui Tariceanu din interiorul partidului.

Astfel ca la congresul din 2009, o opozitie interna grupata in jurul unor figure proeminente precum doi fosti ministri cu bune rezultate ai guvernarii 2004-2008, ministrul transporturilor, Ludovic Orban si ministrul economiei, Varujan Vosganian, si avandu-l in frunte pe curajosul si foarte bunul manuitor al verbului, Crin Antonescu, liderul deputatilor PNL, il va inlocui pe Tariceanu cu mai tanarul si charismaticul Antonescu.

Noua conducere venea pe un val de entuziasm anti-Basescu si promovase la conducerea partidului pe un program de drepata cu o puternica coloratura liberal-conservatoare ce punea accentul pe traditie, identitate, elite, libertati economice si afirmarea individului intr-o societate libera si concurentiala, in virtutea ideii ca PNL-ul trebuie sa devina marele partid unificator al dreptei romanesti.

Intre timp, guvernul condus de Emil Boc, omul de executie fidel pana la sacrificiu lui Basescu, nu reusea deloc sa tina piept provocarilor generate de criza economica care se agraveaza din ce in ce mai mult. Ba chiar, Basescu readuce in tara satrapul financiar mondial expert in falimente de stat ce tocmai fusese alungat de Tariceanu in 2005, FMI.

Pe acest fond, la alegerile din 2009, in urma unui tur 2 extrem de dubios si cu o mare suspiciune de frauda candidatul PSD, Mircea Geoana este invins de Traian Basescu. Inainte de aceasta ,in primul tur, Crin Antonescu reusise sa obtina un onorabil 20 % , obtinand atat ca numar de voturi cat si ca procent cel mai bun scor al unui liberal la alegerile prezidentiale de dupa 1989.

Romania de dupa 2009, saracita, controlata aspru de o putere ilegitima si lipsita de patriotism, demoralizata si adanc divizata se afla in pragul unei dictaturi de facturi mai moderna decat cea traita in cei mai bine de 40 de ani de comunism.

In PNL, Crin Antonescu organizeaza la inceputul lui 2010 un nou congress extraordinar al carui scop este reconfirmarea puterii sale in partid ,reintarirea autoritatii sale ca lider dar si indepartarea catorva din ,,tovarasii de drum,, alaturi de care castigase congresul precedent.

In contextul subrezirii esafodajului democratic romanesc si a presiunii regimului Basescu-PDL, Antonescu isi va asuma o serie de aliante menite sa, “sparga frontul,, in anul electoral 2012.

Alianta cu PC, partid minor si fara larga reprezentare nationala este urmata de infiintarea USL (Uniunea Social Liberala) care reuneste PSD, PNL + PC, in vederea castigarii detasate a alegerilor din 2012.

Intrebarea care revine obsedant, este aceea daca nu cumva o astfel de alianta nu duce spre polarizarea electoratului oferind inca o sansa in plus PD-L spre a reusi un scor multumitor in alegeri. Sunt voci care sustin ca ar fi fost binevenita o astfel de alianta dupa alegeri si chiar ca separat voturile PNL + PSD aduna mai mult decat o fac pe liste comune. O astfel de alianta trebuie vazuta insa din prisma salvarii valorilor democratice in Romania si a eliberarii romanului de sub apasarea ultimilor ani. Aceasta alianta este obligata sa castige si sa faca fata tuturor diversiunilor menite sa compromita sansa revenirii la o Romanie normala si dreapta, de la care a deraiat pe drumul unei republici oligarho-autoritariste de inspiratie ,,latinoamericana“.

Sa speram ca PNL isi va pastra identitatea si valorilor si nu va oferi nicio sansa uzurpatorului partid portocaliu de a se erija in dreapta romaneasca si de a se pretinde fara niciun drept chiar, ”adevaratul partid liberal”!

Sper ca discursul lui Antonescu sa-si regaseasca linia sa national-liberala, si sa evite alunecarile nedorite pe panta social-liberala, linie national-liberala care ne-a convins in adancul firii, pe noi toti cei care credem in PNL ca adevarat purtator al valorilor nationale si democratice romanesti!

 

Daniel Gheorghe

Stratfor.com: „Global Economic Downturn: A Crisis of Political Economy”

Criza capitalismului de cazinou este o criza de sistem. La burse se risipa 10 sau 12 de bugete ale Romaniei. Numai la bursa din Frankfurt astazi sau inregistrat pierderi in valoare de 300 de miliarde de euro. In cifre totale in 8 ore de tranzactie sa risipit de 3 ori datoria externa a Romaniei. Si in final aceste capitalismul de cazinou detine o criza de legitimitate. Un aspect pe care il analizeaza think-tankul nordamerican Stratfor.com.

Sursa informationala + text + idee: Stratfor.com

AutorGeorge Friedman

Classical political economists like Adam Smith or David Ricardo never used the term “economy” by itself. They always used the term “political economy.” For classical economists, it was impossible to understand politics without economics or economics without politics. The two fields are certainly different but they are also intimately linked. The use of the term “economy” by itself did not begin until the late 19th century. Smith understood that while an efficient market would emerge from individual choices, those choices were framed by the political system in which they were made, just as the political system was shaped by economic realities. For classical economists, the political and economic systems were intertwined, each dependent on the other for its existence.

The current economic crisis is best understood as a crisis of political economy. Moreover, it has to be understood as a global crisis enveloping the United States, Europe and China that has different details but one overriding theme: the relationship between the political order and economic life. On a global scale, or at least for most of the world’s major economies, there is a crisis of political economy. Let’s consider how it evolved.

Origin of the Crisis

As we all know, the origin of the current financial crisis was the subprime mortgage meltdown in the United States. To be more precise, it originated in a financial system generating paper assets whose value depended on the price of housing. It assumed that the price of homes would always rise and, at the very least, if the price fluctuated the value of the paper could still be determined. Neither proved to be true. The price of housing declined and, worse, the value of the paper assets became indeterminate. This placed the entire American financial system in a state of gridlock and the crisis spilled over into Europe, where many financial institutions had purchased the paper as well.

From the standpoint of economics, this was essentially a financial crisis: who made or lost money and how much. From the standpoint of political economy it raised a different question: the legitimacy of the financial elite. Think of a national system as a series of subsystems — political, economic, military and so on. Then think of the economic system as being divisible into subsystems — various corporate verticals with their own elites, with one of the verticals being the financial system. Obviously, this oversimplifies the situation, but I’m doing that to make a point. One of the systems, the financial system, failed, and this failure was due to decisions made by the financial elite. This created a massive political problem centered not so much on confidence in any particular financial instrument but on the competence and honesty of the financial elite itself. A sense emerged that the financial elite was either stupid or dishonest or both. The idea was that the financial elite had violated all principles of fiduciary, social and moral responsibility in seeking its own personal gain at the expense of society as a whole.

Fair or not, this perception created a massive political crisis. This was the true systemic crisis, compared to which the crisis of the financial institutions was trivial. The question was whether the political system was capable not merely of fixing the crisis but also of holding the perpetrators responsible. Alternatively, if the financial crisis did not involve criminality, how could the political system not have created laws to render such actions criminal? Was the political elite in collusion with the financial elite?

There was a crisis of confidence in the financial system and a crisis of confidence in the political system. The U.S. government’s actions in September 2008 were designed first to deal with the failures of the financial system. Many expected this would be followed by dealing with the failures of the financial elite, but this is perceived not to have happened. Indeed, the perception is that having spent large sums of money to stabilize the financial system, the political elite allowed the financial elite to manage the system to its benefit.

This generated the second crisis — the crisis of the political elite. The Tea Party movement emerged in part as critics of the political elite, focusing on the measures taken to stabilize the system and arguing that it had created a new financial crisis, this time in excessive sovereign debt. The Tea Party’s perception was extreme, but the idea was that the political elite had solved the financial problem both by generating massive debt and by accumulating excessive state power. Its argument was that the political elite used the financial crisis to dramatically increase the power of the state (health care reform was the poster child for this) while mismanaging the financial system through excessive sovereign debt.

The Crisis in Europe

The sovereign debt question also created both a financial crisis and then a political crisis in Europe. While the American financial crisis certainly affected Europe, the European political crisis was deepened by the resulting recession. There had long been a minority in Europe who felt that the European Union had been constructed either to support the financial elite at the expense of the broader population or to strengthen Northern Europe, particularly France and Germany, at the expense of the periphery — or both. What had been a minority view was strengthened by the recession.

The European crisis paralleled the American crisis in that financial institutions were bailed out. But the deeper crisis was that Europe did not act as a single unit to deal with all European banks but instead worked on a national basis, with each nation focused on its own banks and the European Central Bank seeming to favor Northern Europe in general and Germany in particular. This became the theme particularly when the recession generated disproportionate crises in peripheral countries like Greece.

There are two narratives to the story. One is the German version, which has become the common explanation. It holds that Greece wound up in a sovereign debt crisis because of the irresponsibility of the Greek government in maintaining social welfare programs in excess of what it could fund, and now the Greeks were expecting others, particularly the Germans, to bail them out.

The Greek narrative, which is less noted, was that the Germans rigged the European Union in their favor. Germany is the world’s third-largest exporter, after China and the United States (and closing rapidly on the No. 2 spot). By forming a free trade zone, the Germans created captive markets for their goods. During the prosperity of the first 20 years or so, this was hidden beneath general growth. But once a crisis hit, the inability of Greece to devalue its money — which, as the euro, was controlled by the European Central Bank — and the ability of Germany to continue exporting without any ability of Greece to control those exports exacerbated Greece’s recession, leading to a sovereign debt crisis. Moreover, the regulations generated by Brussels so enhanced the German position that Greece was helpless.

Which narrative is true is not the point. The point is that Europe is facing two political crises generated by economics. One crisis is similar to the American one, which is the belief that Europe’s political elite protected the financial elite. The other is a distinctly European one, a regional crisis in which parts of Europe have come to distrust each other rather vocally. This could become an existential crisis for the European Union.

The Crisis in China

The American and European crises struck hard at China, which, as the world’s largest export economy, is a hostage to external demand, particularly from the United States and Europe. When the United States and Europe went into recession, the Chinese government faced an unemployment crisis. If factories closed, workers would be unemployed, and unemployment in China could lead to massive social instability. The Chinese government had two responses. The first was to keep factories going by encouraging price reductions to the point where profit margins on exports evaporated. The second was to provide unprecedented amounts of credit to enterprises facing default on debts in order to keep them in business.

The strategy worked, of course, but only at the cost of substantial inflation. This led to a second crisis, where workers faced the contraction of already small incomes. The response was to increase incomes, which in turn increased the cost of goods exported once again, making China’s wage rates less competitive, for example, than Mexico’s.

China had previously encouraged entrepreneurs. This was easy when Europe and the United States were booming. Now, the rational move by entrepreneurs was to go offshore or lay off workers, or both. The Chinese government couldn’t afford this, so it began to intrude more and more into the economy. The political elite sought to stabilize the situation — and their own positions — by increasing controls on the financial and other corporate elites.

In different ways, that is what happened in all three places — the United States, Europe and China — at least as first steps. In the United States, the first impulse was to regulate the financial sector, stimulate the economy and increase control over sectors of the economy. In Europe, where there were already substantial controls over the economy, the political elite started to parse how those controls would work and who would benefit more. In China, where the political elite always retained implicit power over the economy, that power was increased. In all three cases, the first impulse was to use political controls.

In all three, this generated resistance. In the United States, the Tea Party was simply the most active and effective manifestation of that resistance. It went beyond them. In Europe, the resistance came from anti-Europeanists (and anti-immigration forces that blamed the European Union’s open border policies for uncontrolled immigration). It also came from political elites of countries like Ireland who were confronting the political elites of other countries. In China, the resistance has come from those being hurt by inflation, both consumers and business interests whose exports are less competitive and profitable.

Not every significant economy is caught in this crisis. Russia went through this crisis years ago and had already tilted toward the political elite’s control over the economy. Brazil and India have not experienced the extremes of China, but then they haven’t had the extreme growth rates of China. But when the United States, Europe and China go into a crisis of this sort, it can reasonably be said that the center of gravity of the world’s economy and most of its military power is in crisis. It is not a trivial moment.

Crisis does not mean collapse. The United States has substantial political legitimacy to draw on. Europe has less but its constituent nations are strong. China’s Communist Party is a formidable entity but it is no longer dealing with a financial crisis. It is dealing with a political crisis over the manner in which the political elite has managed the financial crisis. It is this political crisis that is most dangerous, because as the political elite weakens it loses the ability to manage and control other elites.

It is vital to understand that this is not an ideological challenge. Left-wingers opposing globalization and right-wingers opposing immigration are engaged in the same process — challenging the legitimacy of the elites. Nor is it simply a class issue. The challenge emanates from many areas. The challengers are not yet the majority, but they are not so far away from it as to be discounted. The real problem is that, while the challenge to the elites goes on, the profound differences in the challengers make an alternative political elite difficult to imagine.

The Crisis of Legitimacy

This, then, is the third crisis that can emerge: that the elites become delegitimized and all that there is to replace them is a deeply divided and hostile force, united in hostility to the elites but without any coherent ideology of its own. In the United States this would lead to paralysis. In Europe it would lead to a devolution to the nation-state. In China it would lead to regional fragmentation and conflict.

These are all extreme outcomes and there are many arrestors. But we cannot understand what is going on without understanding two things. The first is that the political economic crisis, if not global, is at least widespread, and uprisings elsewhere have their own roots but are linked in some ways to this crisis. The second is that the crisis is an economic problem that has triggered a political problem, which in turn is making the economic problem worse.

The followers of Adam Smith may believe in an autonomous economic sphere disengaged from politics, but Adam Smith was far more subtle. That’s why he called his greatest book the Wealth of Nations. It was about wealth, but it was also about nations. It was a work of political economy that teaches us a great deal about the moment we are in.

Daurel's Blog

Just another WordPress.com weblog

Florin Citu

A look at financial markets and government policies through the eye of a skeptic

La Stegaru'

"Aveţi de apărat onoarea de a fi stegari!", Nicolae Pescaru

ADRIAN NĂSTASE

Pune întrebarea și, împreună, vom găsi răspunsul!

Sociollogica

"Istoria ne legitimeaza ca singurele partide autentice de centru-dreapta", Crin Antonescu

Carl Schmitt Studien

"Istoria ne legitimeaza ca singurele partide autentice de centru-dreapta", Crin Antonescu

%d blogeri au apreciat: